Template:Short description Template:Infobox economist Armen Albert Alchian (Template:IPAc-en; April 12, 1914Template:Spaced ndashFebruary 19, 2013) was an American economist who made major contributions to microeconomic theory and the theory of the firm. He spent almost his entire career at the University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA), and is credited with turning its economics department into one of the country's best. He is also known as one of the founders of new institutional economics, and widely acknowledged for his work on property rights.
Early life and educationEdit
Armen Albert Alchian was born on April 12, 1914, in Fresno, California, to Armenian-American parents. His father, Alexander H. Alchian (1884–1979),<ref>"California Death Index, 1940-1997," database, FamilySearch (https://familysearch.org/ark:/61903/1:1:VPC3-8M1 Template:Webarchive : 26 November 2014), Alex H Alchian, 06 Feb 1979; Department of Public Health Services, Sacramento.</ref> was born in Erzurum, Ottoman Empire<ref name="asbarez"/> and emigrated to the U.S. in 1901,<ref>"United States Census, 1920", database with images, FamilySearch (https://www.familysearch.org/ark:/61903/1:1:MH3P-G93 Template:Webarchive : 31 January 2021), Alexander Alchian, 1920.</ref> while his mother Lily Normart (1889–1976) was born to Armenian immigrant parents in Fresno.Template:Sfn Her parents were among the first Armenians to settle in the San Joaquin Valley and she was the first Armenian born in Fresno.Template:Sfn<ref name="LATimesobit"/> His parents married in 1909,<ref>"California Marriages, 1850–1945", database, FamilySearch (https://familysearch.org/ark:/61903/1:1:H9W8-2L3Z Template:Webarchive : 24 March 2020), Alexander H. Alchian, 1909.</ref> and Armen had a younger brother, Robert Haig Alchian (1917–1995).Template:Sfn<ref>"Florida Death Index, 1877–1998," database, FamilySearch (https://familysearch.org/ark:/61903/1:1:VVCS-BG4 Template:Webarchive : 25 December 2014), Robert Haig Alchian, 01 Jun 1995; from "Florida Death Index, 1877–1998," index, Ancestry (www.ancestry.com : 2004); citing vol., certificate number 69005, Florida Department of Health, Office of Vital Records, Jacksonville.</ref> His father worked as a musician and a jeweler and the family was of "modest means."Template:Sfn He grew up in the Armenian community, which was initially "subject to intense discrimination."<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> He himself was reportedly subject to anti-Armenian discrimination early in his life.<ref name="Henderson"/> In the 1920s his family hosted General Andranik, an Armenian national hero, in their home for several months.<ref name="Asbarez06">Template:Cite news</ref> Alchian was called "the Armenian Adam Smith" by Michael Intriligator.<ref name="Clough"/><ref name="asbarez"/>
Alchian attended Fresno High School, where he excelled academically and athletically.Template:Sfn He initially enrolled in Fresno State College in 1932 and transferred to Stanford University in 1934, obtaining his bachelor's degree in 1936.Template:Sfn He earned his PhD in philosophy from Stanford in 1943.Template:Sfn<ref name="SinceKeynes"/> His dissertation was titled "The Effects of Changes in the General Wage Structure."Template:Sfn Anthony J. Culyer quoted Kenneth Arrow as saying that Alchian was the "brightest economics student Stanford ever had."<ref name="Culyer"/>
CareerEdit
Alchian worked as a teaching assistant at Stanford (1937–40),<ref name="SinceKeynes"/> and then in 1940–41 he worked at the National Bureau of Economic Research (NBER) and Harvard University and in 1942 at the University of Oregon as an instructor.Template:Sfn He went on to serve in the Army Air Forces as a statistician between 1942 and 1946.<ref name="SinceKeynes"/>Template:Sfn
Alchian joined the Department of Economics at University of California, Los Angeles (UCLA) in 1946.<ref name="UCLA"/> He was initially assistant professor (until 1952), then associate professor (until 1958), and eventually named professor in 1958.<ref name="SinceKeynes"/><ref name="Clough"/> He retired from UCLA in 1984 and was named professor emeritus of economics.<ref name="UCLA"/><ref name="SinceKeynes"/> It was not until 2007, at the age of 93, that he closed his campus office.<ref name="UCLA"/>
In classroom, Alchian adopted the Socratic method and disliked the traditional lecture method.Template:Sfn<ref name="Higgs"/> James M. Buchanan, briefly a colleague in the late 1960s, classified Alchian as "the best blackboard economist" he had ever known.Template:Sfn In 2006 John Riley, chair of the UCLA economics department, stated that Alchian was the "father of the modern-day economics department at UCLA, and set the future for it."<ref name="Crane"/> William R. Allen noted that the department's "golden age" was from 1950 to 1980 because of Alchian's presence and leadership in the department.<ref name="Crane"/>
Alchian was also affiliated with the RAND Corporation between 1946 and 1964 and was a consultant to business firms.<ref name="SinceKeynes"/> At RAND, he is remembered for his work on the hidden costs of regulation.<ref name="UCLA"/> Alchian was the first economist to be employed at RAND and "became the conduit through which many Chicago stalwarts such as Ronald Coase, Gary Becker, and others received lucrative consultancies from RAND."<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Alchian was also involved for around 20 years with the Law and Economics Center, initially affiliated with the University of Rochester, which provided "insight into economic theory to legal scholars and judges."<ref name="UCLA"/> Timothy Muris opined that Alchian was "unexcelled in teaching economics to lawyers."<ref name="Muris"/>
ResearchEdit
Alchian, an applied economist,<ref name="AER97"/> has been described by Robert Higgs as a master of applied price theory.<ref name="Higgs"/> Alchian was a neoclassical economist,<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref> specifically of the Chicago School.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Along with Harold Demsetz, Alchian is considered to be the founder of the "UCLA tradition",<ref name="Clough"/><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> alternatively known as the Los Angeles School.Template:Sfn Read explains: "Theirs is a school which shares some similarities with Chicago's emphasis on the free market, Harvard's tradition of institutional studies, and the strategic thrust of both the RAND Corporation and of the Hoover Institution, to which both contributed intellectually."Template:Sfn
Alchian was also influenced by the Austrian School,Template:Refn especially by the ideas of Ludwig von Mises and Friedrich Hayek.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>Template:Cite news</ref> He was influenced by Mises' Human Action (1949).<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Alchian famously interviewed Hayek in 1978,<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref> during which Alchian told him that he was particularly influenced by two of his articles: "Economics and Knowledge" (1937) and "The Use of Knowledge in Society" (1945).<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> In his turn, Alchian has influenced contemporary Austrian School economists.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>
Alchian, along with James M. Buchanan and Ronald Coase, served as a bridge between the "Old" and "New" Chicago School.<ref name="Boettke&Candela"/> Boettke and Candela argue that these three economists founded the following branches in economics: New Institutional Economics, Law and Economics, and the economics of property rights.<ref name="Boettke&Candela"/> Indeed, Alchian is widely considered one of the founders of the New Institutional Economics.<ref name="BenjaminPERC"/>Template:Efn According to Robert Higgs Alchian had the greatest influence, aside from Coase, "in creating and fostering what has come to be known as the New Institutional Economics, one of the most notable improvements in mainstream economics during the past half century."<ref name="Higgs"/>
A large portion of Alchian's contribution is in property rights.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>Template:Efn<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Henderson argued that Alchian has been most impactful on the economic analysis of property rights and summarized his work on it as follows: "You tell me the rules and I'll tell you what outcomes to expect."<ref name="Henderson"/> Alchian opined that "In essence, economics is the study of property rights over resources."<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Peter Boettke noted in 2015 that Alchian is "recognized as the founder of what was called 'property rights economics' in which he had to re-introduce to the economics profession the important role that property rights play in the determination of economic performance."<ref name="Boettke"/>
While working at RAND in 1954, Alchian conducted the first event study to infer what kind of fuel material was used in the development of hydrogen bombs, the construction of which were secret at the time. He successfully identified lithium as the fusion fuel through publicly available financial data, finding only the stock of Lithium Corporation of America suddenly increased around the hydrogen bomb test Castle Bravo. However, the paper was confiscated and destroyed because it was seen as a threat to national security.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
Notable publicationsEdit
Template:See also Alchian was not prolific and did not author many books and articles.<ref name="Clough"/><ref name="AER97"/> However, his few published works are widely cited.<ref name="Henderson"/><ref name="Clough"/> His writing style is characterized with lack of mathematical formality and is known for its straightforward prose.<ref name="Higgs"/> Harold Demsetz noted that his works are "largely uncluttered with mathematics."<ref name="Clough"/> Henderson praised his clear writing, noting that Alchian was "one of the last economists of his generation to communicate mainly in words and not equations."<ref name="Henderson"/> According to Susan L. Woodward he "had no use for formal models that did not teach us to look somewhere new in the known world, nor had he any patience for findings that relied on fancy econometrics."<ref name="Woodward"/>
In 1964 Alchian and William R. Allen co-authored University Economics, an influential general textbook<ref name="Henderson"/> that has undergone six editions under two titles.<ref name="UCLA"/><ref name="LATimesobit"/> It appeared in 1969 under the name Exchange and Production, and was published a third time in 2018 as Universal Economics.<ref name="SinceKeynes"/><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Mark Blaug described it as standing out "among all of its rivals by a consistent emphasis on the actual or potential role of markets as a device for organising economic life."<ref name="Blaug"/>
The collection of his works was first published in 1977 by Liberty Fund under the title Economic Forces at Work, which contains his main 18 papers.<ref name="SinceKeynes"/> In 2006 Liberty Fund published The Collected Works of Armen A. Alchian in two volumes.<ref name="LATimesobit"/>Template:Sfn
His most significant articles are:<ref name="SinceKeynes"/>
- "Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory" (1950):<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> It is Alchian's first major paper that brought him attention.<ref name="UCLA"/><ref name="Henderson"/> Called one of the "most important contributions to the economic literature,"<ref name="ssrn"/> the article "pioneered the idea that the price system is a Darwinian mechanism in which efficient behaviors survive, regardless of the motives of economic agents."<ref name="AER97"/> According to Karl Brunner, Alchian "demonstrates that even in the absence of rational, profit maximizing or any purposive behavior the economic system produces a rational ordering of resource use patterns."<ref name="Brunner"/> James M. Buchanan described it as a "seminal" paper, which has a "genuinely innovative quality."Template:Sfn
- "Reliability of Progress Curves in Airframe Production" (1963)<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> was completed for the RAND Corporation by 1949, but was not published until 14 years later because it relied on military classified data. A pioneering work,<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Linda Argote and Dennis Epple noted that it stimulated interest in organizational learning curve,<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> while Hubbard stated that it is "credited as the first empirical investigation of learning curves – an important feature of many industries."<ref name="digitopoly"/>
- "Information Costs, Pricing and Resource Unemployment" (1969):<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Mark Blaug argued that it was the "beginning of all later 'job search' theories of unemployment."<ref name="Blaug"/> Alchian considered it his best paper.<ref name="Lott96"/>
- "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization" (1972)։<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Alchian's most cited paper,<ref name="cepr"/> it is "credited with introducing the modern theory of the firm, the article looked at how problems associated with team production, such as shirking while leaving others to do the work, affect the organizational arrangements used by firms."<ref name="UCLA"/> It "has become the basis for much of current organization theory, which now concentrates on the issues of team production and incentives that they emphasized."<ref name="AER97"/> Thomas N. Hubbard argues that it "may be the most influential paper in the economics of organization, catalyzing the development of the field as we know it."<ref name="digitopoly"/><ref name="cepr"/>
In 2011 it was chosen as one of the top 20 articles published in the American Economic Review between 1911 and 2011.<ref>Template:Citation</ref> In fact, it is the most cited of all papers published in the 100 years of existence of the American Economic Review<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> and the 12th most cited economic paper overall between 1970 and mid-2006.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
ViewsEdit
Alchian has been described as a classical liberal<ref>Template:Cite journal
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- Template:Cite book</ref> and libertarian.<ref>Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite journal</ref>Template:Efn He advocated laissez-faire principles and free-market individualism.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite news</ref> He was a member of the Mont Pelerin Society.<ref name="UCLA"/><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref> Axel Leijonhufvud argued that Alchian was skeptical of people who claim they will improve the world by using the powers of the government, but also those calling for abolishing government.Template:Sfn
Alchian listed "self-reliance, independence, responsibility, integrity and trust" as the principles and rules of capitalism and argued that these are antithetical to socialism/communism.<ref name="golf"/> Alchian believed Keynesianism "totally neglects incentives."<ref>Individual and Business Tax Reduction Proposals. Hearing Before the Subcommittee on Taxation and Debt Management Generally of the Committee on Finance. United States Senate. Ninety-Fifth Congress, Second Session. July 14, 1978. U.S. Government Printing Office, Washington, 1978. p. 83</ref> Alchian was a friend of Milton Friedman<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> and Friedman often quoted him: "The one thing you can be most sure of in this life is that everyone will spend someone else's money more liberally than they will spend their own."<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
In the 1960s, Alchian told Eastern Bloc economists that they had to "introduce more private property rights to make markets work the way you think they should work" or else the market allocation will seem to be "perverse or deficient."<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> David Riesman noted that Alchian, like Friedman and Hayek, was "confident about the causal relationships that run from evolution to capitalism, from capitalism to meliorism."<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> One left-wing commentator described Alchian as an "ultra-liberal" economist who vigorously defended the idea that capitalism is characterised by the absence of any substantial power relations between individuals.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Alchian was apparently influenced by neo-Darwinism.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> He, like Friedman, "invoked Darwinism to prove that the market economy is natural."<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Alchian was critical of minimum wage laws.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> During the 1970s energy crisis, Alchian argued for lifting of gas price controls.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
Alchian famously asserted that "95% of the material in economics journals was wrong or irrelevant".<ref name="Sharpe95"/><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
Personal life and deathEdit
Alchian resided in Mar Vista, Los Angeles.<ref name="UCLA"/> In 1940 he married Pauline (née Crouse, 1916–2017),<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> an elementary school teacher, who he had met at Stanford.Template:Sfn<ref name="UCLA"/><ref name="Clough"/> They had two children:<ref name="UCLA"/> Arline Ann Hoel (b. 1943)<ref>"California Birth Index, 1905–1995," database, FamilySearch (https://familysearch.org/ark:/61903/1:1:V2WF-ZDW Template:Webarchive : 27 November 2014), Arline Ann Alchian, 26 Apr 1943; citing Fresno, California, United States, Department of Health Services, Vital Statistics Department, Sacramento.</ref> and Allen Alexander Alchian (b. 1947).<ref>"California Birth Index, 1905–1995," database, FamilySearch (https://familysearch.org/ark:/61903/1:1:V27G-N4Q Template:Webarchive : 27 November 2014), Allen Alexander Alchian, 27 Mar 1947; citing Los Angeles, California, United States, Department of Health Services, Vital Statistics Department, Sacramento.</ref>Template:Sfn
Alchian was an "avid computer user" and an early adopter of email.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
PersonalityEdit
William R. Allen described Alchian as "almost always soft-spoken, unaggressive, and seemingly bemused" and noted that he "eschewed ambitious self-promotion and personal empire-building."<ref name="Allen 2010"/> Daniel Benjamin described him as "fundamentally kind, shy, compassionate, and humble."<ref name="BenjaminPERC"/> William F. Sharpe wrote that Alchian was "personally gentle and traditional," but was "clearly an eccentric economic theorist."<ref name="Sharpe95"/>Template:Sfn Deirdre McCloskey described Alchian as "the soul of courtesy." She wrote that "talking about economics with Armen Alchian is like talking about painting with Pablo Picasso" and that his economics "comes from experience of life."<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Tom G. Palmer wrote of Alchian as a "sober scholar, but not so charismatic."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Susan L. Woodward described him as a "warm and sentimental person."<ref name="Woodward"/> Roger Farmer described him as "selfless" and "amazing human being" who cared "only about promoting ideas."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Steven N.S. Cheung wrote that he "never engaged in self-promotion, and he never cared about journal rankings" and was a "modest gentleman".Template:Sfn He quoted Coase: "Alchian is classical in manners as well as in thought."Template:Sfn
GolfEdit
Alchian was a lifelong golferTemplate:Sfn and a regular visitor to the Rancho Park Golf Course.<ref name="LATimesobit"/> He often played golf with fellow economist George Stigler.<ref name="BenjaminPERC"/> He greatly admired the sport and wrote an opinion piece for The Wall Street Journal in 1977, in which he argued that golf is "not merely a sport. It is an activity, a lifestyle, a behavior, a manifestation of the essential human spirit. Golf's ethic, principles, rules and procedures of play are totally capitalistic. They are antithetical to socialism. Golf requires self-reliance, independence, responsibility, integrity and trust."<ref name="golf">Template:Cite news</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> He preferred to stay home and play golf than to partake in a conference called by President Gerald Ford to "Whip Inflation Now" as it would be "more productive than anything likely to be said in Washington."<ref name="Allen 2010"/>
Last years and deathEdit
One of his last public appearances was in May 2006 at an international conference at the UCLA, organized by Richard G. Hovannisian, on the challenges of sustainable development in Armenia, which was dedicated to Alchian.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name="Asbarez06"/><ref name="azad-hye">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Around six years before his death Alchian's memory deteriorated according to Yoram Barzel.Template:Sfn He suffered from a neurodegenerative disease in the last six years of his life.<ref name="Cheung13"/>Template:Sfn Alchian died of natural causes,<ref name="LATimesobit"/> in his sleep,<ref name="Higgs"/> at his home in Los Angeles on February 19, 2013, at the age of 98.<ref name="UCLA"/>
Recognition and legacyEdit
In 1985 Mark Blaug listed Alchian as one of the "Great Economists Since Keynes".<ref name="Blaug"/> In a 2011 survey of around 300 economics professors in the U.S., Alchian ranked 17th among favorite living economists older than 60. He received the same points as Robert Fogel and Gordon Tullock.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>Template:Efn In 1984 Friedrich Hayek named Alchian and George Stigler his favorite economists "among the not really young ones."<ref name="Hayek1984"/> William R. Allen described him as "one of the superb economic analysts and teachers of the second half of the twentieth century."<ref name="Allen 2010"/> Walter E. Williams and Donald J. Boudreaux describe him as one of the top economists of the twentieth century and probably the greatest microeconomic theorist.Template:Efn
Nobel Prize debateEdit
Alchian never received a Nobel Prize, but numerous economists, such as Hayek,<ref name="Henderson"/> Harry Markowitz,Template:Efn Michael Intriligator,Template:Efn William R. Allen,<ref name="Allen 2010"/> David R. Henderson,<ref>Template:Cite news
- Template:Cite news</ref> Donald J. Boudreaux,<ref>Template:Cite news
</ref> believe he deserved one.Template:Efn Hayek told Henderson in 1975: "There are two economists who deserve the Nobel prize because their work is important but won't get it because they didn't do a lot of work: Ronald Coase and Armen Alchian."<ref name="Henderson"/>Template:Efn Allen nominated Alchian for the Nobel Prize in 1986 and characterized him as "a giant who, because of his lack of pretension, is easily overlooked by laymen and even by some supposed professionals—who has greatly honored his profession and uniquely contributed to its usefulness."<ref name="Allen 2010"/> Axel Leijonhufvud, who was a student and colleague of Alchian for thirty years,Template:Sfn suggested in 1996 that "his lack of self-promotion and his abstentiousness from it I think is what more than anything else has kept him from the Nobel prize so far. I can find no other explanation of the behavior of my countrymen."Template:Sfn
InfluenceEdit
A number of economists have been influenced by Alchian, including several Nobel laurates. Kenneth Arrow was "personally and intellectually closely linked" with Alchian and the latter's influence played a crucial role on Arrow's introduction of the concept of "learning curve" into an economic growth model.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> James M. Buchanan was inspired by Alchian's work on free tuition.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> William F. Sharpe, who took a graduate course taught by Alchian in 1956, named him one of his three mentors, whose approach to research he had attempted to emulate.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref name="UCLA"/> Sharpe called him a "brilliant mind grappling (usually very successfully) with the most difficult concepts in economics in thoroughly creative and innovative ways."<ref name="Sharpe95"/> Elinor Ostrom, an undergraduate student of Alchian, noted that as an institutional theorist, she "really appreciate[s] Alchian's approach" in the 1950 article "Uncertainty, Evolution, and Economic Theory".<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Walter E. Williams called him one of his "tenacious mentors."<ref name="Williams2007"/> William R. Allen named Alchian one of the two individuals who had had the greatest influence on his life, calling him "an older brother."<ref>Template:Cite news</ref> John Lott stated that University Economics was responsible for him becoming an academic and going to UCLA.Template:Sfn
Other noted economists who were students of or were influenced by Alchian include Harold Demsetz,<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Steve Hanke,<ref>Template:Cite news</ref> Henry Manne,<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Yoram Barzel,<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> David Prychitko,<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Anthony J. Culyer,Template:Efn Karl Brunner,Template:Efn Arthur De Vany,<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Jerry Jordan,<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Douglas W. Allen,<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Axel Leijonhufvud,Template:Efn Robert H. Topel.Template:Sfn
Hubbard argues that Alchian's 1972 paper "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization" influenced works in the economics of organization by Bengt Holmström, Oliver Hart, and Paul Milgrom.<ref name="digitopoly"/>
HonorsEdit
- Member of the Mont Pelerin Society (1957)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- President of the Western Economic Association International<ref name="UCLA"/> (1975)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name="Lott96"/>
- Fellow of the American Academy of Arts and Sciences (1978)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- Distinguished Fellow of the American Economic Association (1996)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name="AER97"/>
- Adam Smith Award by the Association of Private Enterprise Education (2000)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- Honorary Fellow of the Institute of Economic Affairs<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- Honorary doctorates
- University of Rochester (1983)<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
- Universidad Francisco Marroquín (2010)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- Tributes
- The Armen A. Alchian Chair in Economic Theory at UCLA<ref name="UCLA"/> was established in July 1997.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- The Armenian Economic Association presents the Armen Alchian Award since 2014.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}</ref>
See alsoEdit
- Daron Acemoglu, another prominent American economist of Armenian origin<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
ReferencesEdit
NotesEdit
CitationsEdit
BibliographyEdit
External linkEdit
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}; via FREE TO CHOOSE NETWORK.
Template:Instecon Template:Chicago school economists Template:Libertarianism