Joseph Schumpeter
Template:Short description Template:Use mdy dates Template:Infobox economist
Joseph Alois Schumpeter ({{#invoke:IPA|main}}; February 8, 1883 – January 8, 1950)<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> was an Austrian political economist. He served briefly as Finance Minister of Austria in 1919. In 1932, he emigrated to the United States to become a professor at Harvard University, where he remained until the end of his career, and in 1939 obtained American citizenship.
Schumpeter was one of the most influential economists of the early 20th century, and popularized creative destruction, a term coined by Werner Sombart.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite news</ref> His magnum opus is considered Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy.
Early life and educationEdit
Schumpeter was born in 1883 in Triesch, Habsburg Moravia (now Třešť in the Czech Republic,<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> then part of Austria-Hungary), to German-speaking Catholic parents. Though both of his grandmothers were Czech, Schumpeter did not acknowledge his Czech ancestry.<ref name="origin1">Template:Cite book</ref> His father, who owned a factory, died when Joseph was only four years old.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> In 1893, Joseph and his mother moved to Vienna.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Schumpeter was a loyal supporter of Franz Joseph I of Austria.<ref name=origin1 />
Schumpeter was educated at the Theresianum and began his career studying law at the University of Vienna under Eugen von Böhm-Bawerk, an economic theorist of the Austrian School. In 1906, he received his doctoral degree from the University of Vienna's faculty of law, with a specialisation in economics.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In 1909, after some study trips, he became a professor of economics and government at the University of Czernowitz in modern-day Ukraine. In 1911, he joined the University of Graz, where he remained until World War I.
In 1913–1914, Schumpeter taught at Columbia University as an invited professor. This invitation marked, according to Wolfgang Stolper, the "high point of his worldly success".<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> He taught economic theory and met Irving Fisher and Wesley Clair Mitchell.<ref name=":1">Template:Cite book</ref> Columbia awarded him an honorary doctorate.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>
In 1918, Schumpeter was a member of the Socialisation Commission established by the Council of the People's Deputies in Germany.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In March 1919, he was invited to take office as Minister of Finance in the Republic of German-Austria. He proposed a capital levy as a way to tackle the war debt and opposed the socialization of the Alpine Mountain plant.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> In 1921, he became president of the private Biedermann Bank. He was also a board member at the Kaufmann Bank. Problems at those banks left Schumpeter in debt. His resignation was a condition of the takeover of the Biedermann Bank in September 1924.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>
From 1925 until 1932, Schumpeter held a chair at the University of Bonn, Germany. He lectured at Harvard in 1927–1928 and 1930. In 1931, he was a visiting professor at the Tokyo College of Commerce.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> In 1932, Schumpeter moved to the United States, and soon began what would become extensive efforts to help fellow central European economists displaced by Nazism.<ref>McCraw, Prophet of Innovation, pp. 231–232.</ref> Schumpeter's last visit to Europe was in 1937.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Schumpeter also became known for his opposition to Marxism, although he still believed the triumph of socialism to be inevitable in the long run.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> He also criticized Franklin Roosevelt's New Deal.<ref>McCraw, pp. 317–321</ref> In 1939, Schumpeter became a US citizen. At the beginning of World War II, the FBI investigated him and his wife, Elizabeth Boody (a prominent scholar of Japanese economics) for Nazi sympathies, but found no evidence of such leanings.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>McCraw, pp. 337–343</ref>
At Harvard, Schumpeter was considered a memorable character, erudite, and even showy in the classroom. He became known for his heavy teaching load and his personal and painstaking interest in his students. He served as the faculty advisor of the Graduate Economics Club and organized private seminars and discussion groups.<ref>McCraw, Prophet of Innovation, pp. 210–217.</ref> Some colleagues thought his views were outdated by Keynesianism, which was fashionable; others resented his criticisms, particularly of their failure to offer an assistant professorship to Paul Samuelson, but recanted when they thought him likely to accept a position at Yale University.<ref>McCraw, pp. 273–278, 306–3311.</ref> This period of his life was characterized by hard work and comparatively little recognition of his massive two-volume book Business Cycles. However, Schumpeter persevered, and in 1942 published what became the most popular of all his works, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, reprinted many times and in many languages in the following decades, as well as cited thousands of times.<ref>McCraw pp. 347 et seq.</ref>
CareerEdit
InfluencesEdit
The source of Schumpeter's dynamic, change-oriented, and innovation-based economics was the historical school of economics. Although his writings could be critical of that perspective, Schumpeter's work on the role of innovation and entrepreneurship can be seen as a continuation of ideas originated by the historical school, especially the work of Gustav von Schmoller and Werner Sombart.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name="GHS">Template:Cite journal</ref> Despite being born in Austria and having trained with many of the same economists, some argue he cannot be categorized with the Austrian School of economics without major qualifications<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> while others maintain the opposite.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Schumpeter was also influenced by Léon Walras and the Lausanne School, calling Walras the "greatest of all economists".<ref>Schumpeter, J. A., 1994 [1954], History of Economic Analysis, Oxford University Press, p. 795</ref>
The Austrian sociologist Rudolf Goldscheid's concept of fiscal sociology influenced Schumpeter's analysis of the tax state.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> A 2012 paper showed that Schumpeter's writings displayed the influence of Francis Galton's work.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
Evolutionary economicsEdit
{{#invoke:Labelled list hatnote|labelledList|Main article|Main articles|Main page|Main pages}} According to Christopher Freeman (2009), "the central point of his whole life work [is]: that capitalism can only be understood as an evolutionary process of continuous innovation and 'creative destruction'".<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>
History of Economic AnalysisEdit
Schumpeter's scholarship is apparent in his posthumous History of Economic Analysis,<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Schumpeter thought that the greatest 18th-century economist was Turgot rather than Adam Smith, and he considered Léon Walras to be the "greatest of all economists", beside whom other economists' theories were "like inadequate attempts to catch some particular aspects of Walrasian truth".<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Schumpeter criticized John Maynard Keynes and David Ricardo for the "Ricardian vice". According to Schumpeter, both Ricardo and Keynes reasoned in terms of abstract models, where they would freeze all but a few variables. Then they could argue that one caused the other in a simple monotonic fashion. This led to the belief that one could easily deduce policy conclusions directly from a highly abstract theoretical model.
In this book, Joseph Schumpeter recognized the implication of a gold monetary standard compared to a fiat monetary standard. In History of Economic Analysis, Schumpeter stated the following: "An 'automatic' gold currency is part and parcel of a laissez-faire and free-trade economy. It links every nation's money rates and price levels with the money rates and price levels of all the other nations that are 'on gold.' However, gold is extremely sensitive to government expenditure and even to attitudes or policies that do not involve expenditure directly, for example, in foreign policy, certain policies of taxation, and, in general, precisely all those policies that violate the principles of [classical] liberalism. This is the reason why gold is so unpopular now and also why it was so popular in a bourgeois era."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Business cyclesEdit
Schumpeter's relationships with the ideas of other economists were quite complex in his most important contributions to economic analysis – the theory of business cycles and development. Following neither Walras nor Keynes, Schumpeter starts in The Theory of Economic Development<ref>Schumpeter, J.A. The theory of economic development: an inquiry into profits, capital, credit, interest, and the business cycle translated from the German by Redvers Opie (1961) New York: OUP</ref> with a treatise of circular flow which, excluding any innovations and innovative activities, leads to a stationary state.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> The stationary state is, according to Schumpeter, described by Walrasian equilibrium. The hero of his story is the entrepreneur.
The entrepreneur disturbs this equilibrium and is the prime cause of economic development, which proceeds cyclically along with several time scales. In fashioning this theory connecting innovations, cycles, and development, Schumpeter kept alive the Russian Nikolai Kondratiev's ideas on 50-year cycles, Kondratiev waves.
Schumpeter suggested a model in which the four main cycles, Kondratiev (54 years), Kuznets (18 years), Juglar (9 years), and Kitchin (about 4 years) can be added together to form a composite waveform. A Kondratiev wave could consist of three lower-degree Kuznets waves.<ref>Recent research suggests that the Kuznets swing could be regarded as the third harmonic of the Kondratiev wave – see Template:Cite journal</ref> Each Kuznets wave could, itself, be made up of two Juglar waves. Similarly two (or three) Kitchin waves could form a higher degree Juglar wave. If each of these were in phase; more importantly, if the downward arc of each was simultaneous so that the nadir of each was coincident, it would explain disastrous slumps and consequent depressions. As far as the segmentation of the Kondratiev Wave, Schumpeter never proposed such a fixed model. He saw these cycles varying in time – although in a tight time frame by coincidence – and for each to serve a specific purpose.
KeynesianismEdit
In Schumpeter's theory, Walrasian equilibrium is not adequate to capture the key mechanisms of economic development. Schumpeter also thought that the institution enabling the entrepreneur to buy the resources needed to realize his vision was a well-developed capitalist financial system, including a whole range of institutions for granting credit. One could divide economists among (1) those who emphasized "real" analysis and regarded money as merely a "veil" and (2) those who thought monetary institutions were important and money could be a separate driving force. Both Schumpeter and Keynes were among the latter.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Demise of capitalismEdit
Template:More citations needed section Schumpeter's most popular book in English is probably Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy. While he agrees with Karl Marx that capitalism will collapse and be replaced by socialism, Schumpeter predicts a different way this will come about. While Marx predicted that capitalism would be overthrown by a violent proletarian revolution, which occurred in the least capitalist countries, Schumpeter believed that capitalism would gradually weaken itself and eventually collapse. Specifically, the success of capitalism would lead to corporatism and to values hostile to capitalism, especially among intellectuals.
"Intellectuals" are a social class in a position to critique societal matters for which they are not directly responsible and to stand up for the interests of other classes. Intellectuals tend to have a negative outlook on capitalism, even while relying on it for prestige because their professions rely on antagonism toward it. The growing number of people with higher education is a great advantage of capitalism, according to Schumpeter. Yet, unemployment and a lack of fulfilling work will lead to intellectual critique, discontent, and protests.
Parliaments will increasingly elect social democratic parties, and democratic majorities will vote for restrictions on entrepreneurship. Increasing workers' self-management, industrial democracy and regulatory institutions would evolve non-politically into "liberal capitalism". Thus, the intellectual and social climate needed for thriving entrepreneurship will be replaced by some form of "laborism". This will exacerbate "creative destruction" (a borrowed phrase to denote an endogenous replacement of old ways of doing things by new ways), which will ultimately undermine and destroy the capitalist structure.
Schumpeter emphasizes throughout this book that he is analyzing trends, not engaging in political advocacy.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
William Fellner, in the book Schumpeter's Vision: Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy After 40 Years, noted that Schumpeter saw any political system in which the power was fully monopolized as fascist.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>
Democratic theoryEdit
In the same book, Schumpeter expounded on a theory of democracy that sought to challenge what he called the "classical doctrine".<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> He disputed the idea that democracy was a process by which the electorate identified the common good, and politicians carried this out for them. He argued this was unrealistic, and that people's ignorance and superficiality meant that they were largely manipulated by politicians, who set the agenda. Furthermore, he claimed that even if the common good was possible to find, it would still not make clear the means needed to reach its end, since citizens do not have the requisite knowledge to design government policy.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> This made a 'rule by the people' concept both unlikely and undesirable. Instead, he advocated a minimalist model, much influenced by Max Weber, whereby democracy is the mechanism for competition between leaders, much like a market structure. Although periodic votes by the general public legitimize governments and keep them accountable, the policy program is very much seen as their own and not that of the people, and the participatory role of individuals is usually severely limited.
Schumpeter defined democracy as the method by which people elect representatives in competitive elections to carry out their will.<ref name="Przeworski">Template:Cite book</ref> This definition has been described as simple, elegant and parsimonious, making it clearer to distinguish political systems that either fulfill or fail these characteristics.<ref name="RussianPolitics">Template:Cite book</ref> This minimalist definition stands in contrast to broader definitions of democracy, which may emphasize aspects such as "representation, accountability, equality, participation, justice, dignity, rationality, security, freedom".<ref name="Przeworski" /> Within such a minimalist definition, states which other scholars say have experienced democratic backsliding and which lack civil liberties, a free press, the rule of law and a constrained executive, would still be considered democracies.<ref name="RussianPolitics" /><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> For Schumpeter, the formation of a government is the endpoint of the democratic process, which means that for the purposes of his democratic theory, he has no comment on what kinds of decisions that the government can take to be a democracy.<ref name="MeasuringDemocracy">Template:Cite book</ref> Schumpeter faced pushback on his theory from other democratic theorists, such as Robert Dahl, who argued that there is more to democracy than simply the formation of government through competitive elections.<ref name="MeasuringDemocracy" />
Schumpeter's view of democracy has been described as "elitist", as he criticizes the rationality and knowledge of voters, and expresses a preference for politicians making decisions.<ref name="Piano">Template:Cite journal</ref><ref name="Munck">Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Democracy is therefore in a sense a means to ensure circulation among elites.<ref name="Munck" /> However, studies by Natasha Piano of the University of Chicago emphasize that Schumpeter had substantial disdain for elites as well.<ref name="Piano"/><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
EntrepreneurshipEdit
The field of entrepreneurship theory owed much to Schumpeter's contributions. His fundamental theories are often referred to<ref name="Fontana">Template:Cite journal</ref> as Mark I and Mark II. In Mark I, Schumpeter argued that the innovation and technological change of a nation come from entrepreneurs or wild spirits. He coined the word Unternehmergeist, German for "entrepreneur-spirit", and asserted that "... the doing of new things or the doing of things that are already being done in a new way"<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> stemmed directly from the efforts of entrepreneurs.
Schumpeter developed Mark II while a professor at Harvard. Many social economists and popular authors of the day argued that large businesses had a negative effect on the standard of living of ordinary people. Contrary to this prevailing opinion, Schumpeter argued that the agents that drive innovation and the economy are large companies that have the capital to invest in research and development of new products and services and to deliver them to customers more cheaply, thus raising their standard of living. In one of his seminal works, Capitalism, Socialism and Democracy, Schumpeter wrote:
<templatestyles src="Template:Blockquote/styles.css" />
As soon as we go into details and inquire into the individual items in which progress was most conspicuous, the trail leads not to the doors of those firms that work under conditions of comparatively free competition but precisely to the door of the large concerns – which, as in the case of agricultural machinery, also account for much of the progress in the competitive sector – and a shocking suspicion dawns upon us that big business may have had more to do with creating that standard of life than with keeping it down.<ref>Template:Cite book
</ref>{{#if:|{{#if:|}}
— {{#if:|, in }}Template:Comma separated entries}}
{{#invoke:Check for unknown parameters|check|unknown=Template:Main other|preview=Page using Template:Blockquote with unknown parameter "_VALUE_"|ignoreblank=y| 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | author | by | char | character | cite | class | content | multiline | personquoted | publication | quote | quotesource | quotetext | sign | source | style | text | title | ts }}
Template:As of Mark I and Mark II arguments are considered complementary.<ref name="Fontana"/>
Cycles and long wave theoryEdit
Schumpeter was the most influential thinker to argue that long cycles are caused by innovation and are an incident of it. His treatise on how business cycles developed was based on Kondratiev's ideas which attributed the causes very differently. Schumpeter's treatise brought Kondratiev's ideas to the attention of English-speaking economists. Kondratiev fused important elements that Schumpeter missed. Yet, the Schumpeterian variant of the long-cycles hypothesis, stressing the initiating role of innovations, commands the widest attention today.<ref name="ReferenceB">Freeman, Christopher, ed. Long Wave Theory, International Library of Critical Writings in Economics: Edward Elgar, 1996</ref> In Schumpeter's view, technological innovation is the cause of both cyclical instability and economic growth. Fluctuations in innovation cause fluctuations in investment and those cause cycles in economic growth. Schumpeter sees innovations as clustering around certain points in time that he refers to as "neighborhoods of equilibrium" when entrepreneurs perceive that risk and returns warrant innovative commitments. These clusters lead to long cycles by generating periods of acceleration in aggregate growth.<ref>Rosenberg, Nathan. "Technological Innovation and Long Waves." In Exploring the Black Box: Technology, Economics, and History, 62–84. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press, 1994.</ref>
The technological view of change needs to demonstrate that changes in the rate of innovation govern changes in the rate of new investments and that the combined impact of innovation clusters takes the form of fluctuation in aggregate output or employment. The process of technological innovation involves extremely complex relations among a set of key variables: inventions, innovations, diffusion paths, and investment activities. The impact of technological innovation on aggregate output is mediated through a succession of relationships that have yet to be explored systematically in the context of the long wave. New inventions are typically primitive, their performance is usually poorer than existing technologies and the cost of their production is high. A production technology may not yet exist, as is often the case in major chemical and pharmaceutical inventions. The speed with which inventions are transformed into innovations and diffused depends on the actual and expected trajectory of performance improvement and cost reduction.<ref name="jstor.org">Template:Cite journal</ref>
InnovationEdit
Schumpeter identified innovation as the critical dimension of economic change.<ref name="Pol">Template:Cite book</ref> He argued that economic change revolves around innovation, entrepreneurial activities, and market power.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> He sought to prove that innovation-originated market power can provide better results than the invisible hand and price competition.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> He argued that technological innovation often creates temporary monopolies, allowing abnormal profits that would soon be competed away by rivals and imitators. These temporary monopolies were necessary to provide the incentive for firms to develop new products and processes.<ref name="Pol"/>
Doing BusinessEdit
The World Bank's "Doing Business" report was influenced by Schumpeter's focus on removing impediments to creative destruction. The creation of the report is credited in part to his work.
Personal lifeEdit
Schumpeter was married three times.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> His first wife was Gladys Ricarde Seaver, an Englishwoman nearly 12 years his senior (married 1907, separated 1913, divorced 1925). His best man at his wedding was his friend and Austrian jurist Hans Kelsen. His second was Anna Reisinger, 20 years his junior and daughter of the concierge of the apartment where he grew up. As a divorced man, he and his bride converted to Lutheranism to marry.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> They married in 1925, but within a year, she died in childbirth. The loss of his wife and newborn son came only weeks after Schumpeter's mother had died. Five years after arriving in the US, in 1937, at the age of 54, Schumpeter married the American economic historian Dr. Elizabeth Boody (1898–1953), who helped him popularize his work and edited what became their magnum opus, the posthumously published History of Economic Analysis.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Elizabeth assisted him with his research and English writing until his death.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Schumpeter claimed that he had set himself three goals in life: to be the greatest economist in the world, to be the best horseman in all of Austria, and the greatest lover in all of Vienna. He said he had reached two of his goals, but he never said which two,<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Schumpeter's Diary as quoted in "Prophet of Innovation" by Thomas McCraw, p. 4.</ref> although he is reported to have said that there were too many fine horsemen in Austria for him to succeed in all his aspirations.<ref>P. A. Samuelson and W. D. Nordhaus, Economics (1998, p. 178)</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Schumpeter died in his home in Taconic, Connecticut, at the age of 66, on the night of January 8, 1950.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
LegacyEdit
For some time after his death, Schumpeter's views were most influential among various heterodox economists, especially Europeans, who were interested in industrial organization, evolutionary theory, and economic development, and who tended to be on the other end of the political spectrum from Schumpeter and were also often influenced by Keynes, Karl Marx, and Thorstein Veblen. Robert Heilbroner was one of Schumpeter's most renowned pupils, who wrote extensively about him in The Worldly Philosophers. In the journal Monthly Review, John Bellamy Foster wrote of that journal's founder Paul Sweezy, one of the leading Marxist economists in the United States and a graduate assistant of Schumpeter's at Harvard, that Schumpeter "played a formative role in his development as a thinker".<ref>Template:Cite magazine</ref> Other outstanding students of Schumpeter's include the economists Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen and Hyman Minsky and John Kenneth Galbraith and former chairman of the Federal Reserve, Alan Greenspan.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Future Nobel Laureate Robert Solow was his student at Harvard, and he expanded on Schumpeter's theory.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Today, Schumpeter has a following outside standard textbook economics, in areas such as economic policy, management studies, industrial policy, and the study of innovation. Schumpeter was probably the first scholar to develop theories about entrepreneurship. For instance, the European Union's innovation program, and its main development plan, the Lisbon Strategy, are influenced by Schumpeter. The International Joseph A. Schumpeter Society awards the Schumpeter Prize.
The Schumpeter School of Business and Economics opened in October 2008 at the University of Wuppertal, Germany. According to University President Professor Lambert T. Koch, "Schumpeter will not only be the name of the Faculty of Management and Economics, but this is also a research and teaching programme related to Joseph A. Schumpeter."<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
On September 17, 2009, The Economist inaugurated a column on business and management named "Schumpeter".<ref name="TakingFlight">Template:Cite magazine</ref> The publication has a history of naming columns after significant figures or symbols in the covered field, including naming its British affairs column after former editor Walter Bagehot and its European affairs column after Charlemagne. The initial Schumpeter column praised him as a "champion of innovation and entrepreneurship" whose writing showed an understanding of the benefits and dangers of business that proved to be far ahead of its time.<ref name="TakingFlight"/>
Schumpeter's thoughts inspired the economic theory of Adam Przeworski.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
Major worksEdit
BooksEdit
- Translated as: Template:Cite book Translated by: Bruce A. McDaniel
- Template:Cite book Pdf of preface by F.A. Hayek and first eight pages.
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book Translated from the 1911 original German, Theorie der wirtschaftlichen Entwicklung.
- Template:Cite book Translated from the 1912 original German, Epochen der Dogmen – und Methodengeschichte. Pdf version.
- Reprinted in hardback as: Template:Cite book
- Reprinted in paperback as: Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book Reprinted by the University of Michigan Library
- Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as: Template:Citation
- Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as: Template:Citation
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as: Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Citation
- Template:Citation
- Template:Citation
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Citation
- Template:Citation
- See also the English translation: Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Citation
- Template:Citation
- Originally printed as: Template:Cite journal
- Template:Citation
- Template:Citation
- Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as: Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as: Template:Cite book
- Reprinted as: Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Schumpeter, Joseph A. (1953). Aufsätze zur Soziologie. Tubingen: J. C. B. Mohr.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
- Template:Cite book Edited from a manuscript by Elizabeth Boody Schumpeter.
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Originally printed as: Template:Cite book Reprinted in 2008.
- Template:Cite book
Journal articlesEdit
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal Continued on pp. 88–91.
- Reprinted as: Template:Citation
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal The first 2 chapters of A Treatise on Money
- Template:Cite journal Translated from a speech given in German by Schumpeter, Wie studiert man Sozialwissenschaft.
MemoriamsEdit
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
ReviewsEdit
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
See alsoEdit
ReferencesEdit
Further readingEdit
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite encyclopedia
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite book
- Template:Cite journal
- Template:Cite book
External linksEdit
Template:Sister project Template:Sister project
- Template:Cite encyclopedia
- Template:Cite journal
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- {{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation
|CitationClass=web }}
- Template:Find a Grave
- Śledzik, K., Szmelter-Jarosz, A., Schmidt, E. K., Bielawski, K., & Declich, A. (2023). Are Schumpeter’s Innovations Responsible? A Reflection on the Concept of Responsible (Research and) Innovation from a Neo-Schumpeterian Perspective. Journal of the Knowledge Economy, 14(4), 5065–5085.
Template:S-start Template:S-off Template:S-bef Template:S-ttl Template:S-aft Template:S-end
Template:Portal bar Template:Historical school economists Template:Presidents of the Econometric Society Template:Presidents of the American Economic Association Template:Presidents of the International Economic Association Template:Authority control