Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Complete contract
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
A '''complete contract''' is an important concept from [[contract theory]]. If the parties to an agreement could specify their respective rights and duties for every possible future state of the world, their contract would be complete. There would be no gaps in the terms of the contract. However, because it would be prohibitively expensive to write a complete contract, contracts in the real world are usually incomplete. When a dispute arises and the case falls into a gap in the contract, either the parties must engage in [[bargaining]] or the courts must step in and fill in the gap. The idea of a complete contract is closely related to the notion of [[default rule]]s, e.g. legal rules that will fill the gap in a contract in the absence of an agreed upon provision. In economics, the field of [[contract theory]] can be subdivided into the theory of complete contracts and the theory of [[incomplete contracts]].<ref>{{Cite book|title = Contract theory|last = Bolton|first = Patrick|publisher = MIT Press|year = 2005|last2 = Dewatripont|first2 = Matthias}}</ref> Complete contracting theory is also called agency theory (or [[principal-agent theory]]) and closely related to (Bayesian) [[mechanism design]] and [[implementation theory]]. The two most important classes of models in complete contracting theory are [[adverse selection]] and [[moral hazard]] models. In this part of contract theory, every conceivable contractual arrangement between the contractual parties is allowed, provided it is feasible given the relevant technological and information constraints. In the presence of asymmetric information, the optimization problems can be handled due to the [[revelation principle]]. A leading textbook exposition of complete contract theory is Laffont and Martimort (2002).<ref>{{Cite book|title = The theory of incentives: The principal-agent model|last = Laffont|first = Jean-Jacques|publisher = Princeton University Press|year = 2009|last2 = Martimort|first2 = David}}</ref> In contrast, [[Incomplete contracts|incomplete contracting]] models consider situations in which only a restricted class of contracts is allowed, e.g. only simple ownership structures can be contractually specified in the [[Theory of the firm|Grossman-Hart-Moore theory of the firm]].<ref>{{Cite book|title = Firms, contracts, and financial structure.|last = Hart|first = Oliver|publisher = Oxford University Press|year = 1995}}</ref>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)