Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Two-part tariff
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{More footnotes|date=February 2010}} A '''two-part tariff''' (TPT) is a form of [[price discrimination]] wherein the price of a [[product (business)|product]] or [[Service (economics)|service]] is composed of two parts β a lump-sum fee as well as a per-unit charge.<ref>Palgrave Dictionary of Economics: http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2011_T000188 {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20171214014411/http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2011_T000188 |date=2017-12-14 }}</ref><ref>Robert S. Pindyck and Daniel L. Rubinfeld: ''Microeconomics'', 8th edition, Pearson, 2013, p. 414.</ref> In general, such a pricing technique only occurs in partially or fully [[monopoly|monopolistic]] [[market (economics)|market]]s. It is designed to enable the firm to capture more [[consumer surplus]] than it otherwise would in a non-discriminating pricing environment. Two-part tariffs may also exist in [[Competition (economics)|competitive markets]] when consumers are uncertain about their ultimate demand. Health club consumers, for example, may be uncertain about their level of future commitment to an exercise regimen. Two-part tariffs are easy to implement when connection or entrance fees (first part) can be charged along with a price per unit consumed (second part).<ref>{{Cite book|last=Phillips|first=L|title=Palgrave Macmillan (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics|publisher=Palgrave Macmillan|year=1987|isbn=978-1-349-95121-5|location=London}}</ref> Depending on the homogeneity of demand, the lump-sum fee charged varies, but the rational firm will set the per unit charge '''above or equal to''' the [[marginal cost]] of production, and '''below or equal to''' the price the firm would charge in a [[Monopoly#Monopolistic pricing|perfect monopoly]]. Under [[Competition (economics)|competition]] the per-unit price is set below marginal cost.<ref>Hayes, B. (1987), p. 42.</ref> An important element to remember concerning two-part tariffs is that the product or service offered by the firm must be identical to all consumers, hence, price charged may vary, but ''not due to different costs borne by the firm'', as this would imply a [[Differentiation (marketing)|differentiated]] product. Thus, while credit cards which charge an annual fee plus a per-transaction fee is a good example of a two-part tariff, a fixed fee charged by a car rental company in addition to a per-kilometer fuel fee is not so good, because the fixed fee may reflect fixed costs such as registration and insurance which the firm must recoup in this manner. This can make the identification of two-part tariffs difficult.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)