Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Allocative efficiency
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
== Description == In [[economics]], allocative efficiency entails production at the point on the [[production possibilities frontier]] that is optimal for society. In [[contract theory]], allocative efficiency is achieved in a contract in which the skill demanded by the offering party and the skill of the agreeing party are the same. Resource allocation efficiency includes two aspects: # At the macro aspect, it is the allocation efficiency of social resources, which is achieved through the economic system arrangements of the entire society. # The micro aspect is the efficient use of resources, which can be understood as the production efficiency of the organization, which can be improved through innovation and progress within the organizations. Although there are different standards of evaluation for the concept of allocative efficiency, the basic principle asserts that in any economic system, choices in resource allocation produce both "winners" and "losers" relative to the choice being evaluated. The principles of rational choice, individual maximization, [[utilitarianism]] and market theory further suppose that the outcomes for winners and losers can be identified, compared, and measured. Under these basic premises, the goal of attaining allocative efficiency can be defined according to some principles where some allocations are subjectively better than others. For example, an economist might say that a policy change is an allocative improvement as long as those who benefit from the change (winners) gain more than the losers lose (see [[Kaldor–Hicks efficiency]]). An allocatively efficient economy produces an "optimal mix" of commodities.<ref>Kim, A., ''Decentralization and the Provision of Public Services: Framework and Implementation'' ([[Washington, D.C.]]: [[World Bank Group|The World Bank]], 2008), [https://books.google.com/books?id=nhGNafGBYvAC&pg=PA9 p. 9].</ref>{{rp|9}} A firm is allocatively efficient when its price is equal to its [[marginal costs]] (that is, P = MC) in a perfect market. The [[demand]] curve coincides with the [[marginal utility]] curve, which measures the (private) benefit of the additional unit, while the [[Supply (economics)|supply]] curve coincides with the [[marginal cost]] curve, which measures the (private) cost of the additional unit. In a perfect market, there are no externalities, implying that the demand curve is also equal to the social benefit of the additional unit, while the supply curve measures the social cost of the additional unit. Therefore, the market equilibrium, where demand meets supply, is also where the marginal social benefit equals the marginal social costs. At this point, the net social benefit is maximized, meaning this is the allocative efficient outcome. When a market fails to allocate resources efficiently, there is said to be [[market failure]]. Market failure may occur because of imperfect knowledge, differentiated goods, concentrated [[market power]] (e.g., [[monopoly]] or [[oligopoly]]), or [[externalities]]. In the single-price model, at the point of allocative efficiency price is equal to marginal cost.<ref>{{cite book|title=Matters of Principle|last=Markovits|first=Richard|publisher=[[New York University Press]]|year=1998|isbn=978-0-8147-5513-6|location=[[New York City|New York]]}}</ref><ref>{{cite book|title=Truth or Economics|last=Markovits|first=Richard|publisher=[[Yale University Press]]|year=2008|isbn=978-0-300-11459-1|location=[[New Haven]]}}</ref> At this point the social surplus is maximized with no [[deadweight loss]] (the latter being the value society puts on that level of output produced minus the value of resources used to achieve that level). Allocative efficiency is the main tool of welfare analysis to measure the impact of markets and public policy upon society and subgroups being made better or worse off. It is possible to have [[Pareto efficiency]] without allocative efficiency: in such a situation, it is impossible to reallocate resources in such a way that someone gains and no one loses (hence we have Pareto efficiency), yet it would be possible to reallocate in such a way that gainers gain more than losers lose (hence with such a reallocation, we do not have allocative efficiency).<ref>Beardshaw, J., ''Economics: A Student's Guide'' ([[Upper Saddle River, NJ]]: [[FT Press]], 1984), [https://books.google.com/books?id=UCU4rPntmkUC&pg=PT419 p. 397].</ref>{{rp|397}} Also, for an extensive discussion of various types of allocative efficiency in a production context and their estimations see [[Robin Sickles|Sickles]] and Zelenyuk (2019, Chapter 3, etc).<ref>Sickles, R., & Zelenyuk, V. (2019). [https://assets.cambridge.org/97811070/36161/frontmatter/9781107036161_frontmatter.pdf ''Measurement of Productivity and Efficiency: Theory and Practice'']. [[Cambridge]]: [[Cambridge University Press]]. doi:10.1017/9781139565981</ref> In view of the Pareto efficiency measurement method, it is difficult to use in actual operation, including the use of human and material resources, which is hard to achieve a full range of efficiency allocation, and it is mainly to make judgments from the allocation of funds; therefore, analyzing the funds in the stock market. Allocation efficiency is used to determine the efficiency of resource allocation in the capital market. In a perfectly competitive market, capital market resources should be allocated among capital markets under the principle of the highest marginal benefit. Therefore, the most important measurement standard in the capital market is to observe whether capital flows into the enterprise with the best operating efficiency. The most efficient companies should also get a large amount of capital investment, and the less efficient companies should get less capital investment. There are three conditions that come with Pareto efficiency ; Best trade outcome : Even if you trade again, individuals cannot get greater benefits from it. At this time, for any two consumers, the marginal substitution rate of any two commodities is the same, and the utility of the two consumers is maximized at the same time. ; Optimal production: : This economy must be on the boundary of its own production possibilities. At this time, for any two producers who produce different products, the marginal technology substitution rate of the two production factors that need to be input is the same, and the output of the two consumers is maximized at the same time. ; Optimal product mix: : The combination of products produced by the economy must reflect consumer preferences. At this time, the marginal rate of substitution between any two commodities must be the same as the marginal product conversion rate of any producer between these two commodities.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)