Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Marginal propensity to consume
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
== Background == Mathematically, the <math>\mathit{MPC}</math> function is expressed as the [[derivative]] of the [[consumption function]] <math>C</math> with respect to disposable income <math>Y</math>, i.e., the instantaneous slope of the <math>C</math>-<math>Y</math> curve. :<math>\mathit{MPC}=\frac{dC}{dY}</math> or, approximately, :<math>\mathit{MPC} = \frac{\Delta C}{\Delta Y}</math>, where <math>\Delta C</math> is the change in consumption, and <math>\Delta Y</math> is the change in disposable income that produced the consumption. Marginal propensity to consume can be found by dividing change in consumption by a change in income, or <math>\mathit{MPC}=\Delta C/\Delta Y</math>. The MPC can be explained with the simple example: {| class="wikitable" |- ! Income!! Consumption |- | 120 || 120 |- | 180 || 170 |} Here <math>\Delta C= 50</math>; <math>\Delta Y= 60</math> Therefore, <math>\mathit{MPC}=\Delta C/\Delta Y= 50/60= 0.83</math> or 83%. For example, suppose you receive a bonus with your paycheck, and it's $500 on top of your normal annual earnings. You suddenly have $500 more in income than you did before. If you decide to spend $400 of this marginal increase in income on a new business suit, your marginal propensity to consume will be 0.8 (<math>\$400/\$500</math>). [[File:MPC.png|thumb]] The marginal propensity to consume is measured as the ratio of the change in consumption to the change in income, thus giving us a figure between 0 and 1. The MPC can be more than one if the subject borrowed money or dissaved to finance expenditures higher than their income. The MPC can also be less than zero if an increase in income leads to a reduction in consumption (which might occur if, for example, the increase in income makes it worthwhile to save up for a particular purchase). One minus the MPC equals the [[marginal propensity to save]] (in a two sector closed economy), which is crucial to [[Keynesian economics]] and a key variable in determining the value of the [[Multiplier (economics)|multiplier]]. In symbols, we have:<math>\frac{\Delta C}{\Delta Y} + \frac{\Delta S}{\Delta Y} = 1</math>. In a standard Keynesian model, the MPC is less than the [[average propensity to consume]] (APC) because in the short-run some (autonomous) consumption does not change with income. Falls (increases) in income do not lead to reductions (increases) in consumption because people reduce (add to) savings to stabilize consumption. Over the long-run, as wealth and income rise, consumption also rises; the marginal propensity to consume out of long-run income is closer to the average propensity to consume. The MPC is not strongly influenced by interest rates; consumption tends to be stable relative to income. In theory one might think that higher interest rates would induce more saving (the substitution effect) but higher interest rates also mean than people do not have to save as much for the future. Economists often distinguish between the marginal propensity to consume out of permanent income, and the average propensity to consume out of temporary income, because if consumers expect a change in income to be permanent, then they have a greater incentive to increase their consumption.<ref>{{cite book |first1=Robert |last1=Barro |first2=Vittorio |last2=Grilli |year=1994 |title=European Macroeconomics |publisher=Macmillan |isbn=0333577647 |pages=417β8 }}</ref> This implies that the Keynesian [[Multiplier (economics)|multiplier]] should be ''larger'' in response to permanent changes in income than it is in response to temporary changes in income (though the earliest Keynesian analyses ignored these subtleties). However, the distinction between permanent and temporary changes in income is often subtle in practice, and it is often quite difficult to designate a particular change in income as being permanent or temporary. What is more, the marginal propensity to consume should also be affected by factors such as the prevailing interest rate and the general level of [[consumer surplus]] that can be derived from purchasing.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)