Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Prodnalog
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==History== The transition to prodnalog was the first act of the [[New Economic Policy]] and a necessary incentive for increasing [[Soviet Union|Soviet]] [[agricultural]] production . The [[peasant]]s knew in advance how much produce they would have to surrender to the state. The [[Tax rate|rate]] of prodnalog was much smaller than [[prodrazvyorstka]]. For comparison, in 1920-1921 the peasants surrendered to the state 367 million ''[[pood]]s'' (6,010,000 [[tonne|metric tons]]) of [[cereal]]s through prodrazvyorstka, as opposed to 240 million poods (3,930,000 metric tons) in 1921-1922 through prodnalog. During the first year of introduction of prodnalog, a significant amount of [[bread]] and other products remained at peasant [[household]]s' disposal, which provided an incentive for peasants to develop their own household [[economy]], widen the sowing areas, increase the total number of [[livestock]] and [[productivity]] of [[agriculture|crops]]. The rate of prodnalog on each kind of agricultural product was determined depending on local conditions and prosperity of a given peasant household. The Soviet state adhered to a policy of [[progressive taxation]]; the highest rate of prodnalog had to be paid by the [[kulak]] households. In March and April 1921, a number of [[Soviet Decrees]] introduced a natural tax on bread, [[potato]], oilseeds, [[egg (food)|eggs]], [[dairy products]], [[wool]], [[Hide (skin)|hides]], [[flax]] and [[Industrial hemp|hemp]] linen, [[tobacco]] etc. The collection of agricultural goods in excess of prodnalog, if necessary, was intended to be made on a [[barter]] basis by giving peasants manufactured goods. In order to accelerate the expansion of [[commodity]] circulation, create necessary conditions for developing [[farming]] and [[Industrial sector|industry]] and speed up the productive forces of the country, the government encouraged small-scale production all over [[Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic|Soviet Union]]. The introduction of prodnalog revived the trade and created a different kind of relations between the city and the village. By the decision of the [[12th Congress of the RCP(b)|12th Congress]] of the [[CPSU|RCP(b)]] (April 1923), prodnalog and other taxes in the rural areas were exchanged for a universal direct agricultural tax (decree of the All-Russian Central Executive Committee and [[Sovnarkom]] on May 10, 1923). The latter would be collected in [[monetary]] form starting in 1924, with the establishment of [[hard currency]] in the [[USSR]]. However bad harvests combined with the increased needs for hard currency to support industrialization in the [[Soviet Union|industrialization]] had led to grain procurement crises. [[Stalin]] blamed [[kulak]]s for the crisis, and in 1928 extraordinary measures were introduced, including grain confiscation. This crisis was an additional motive for Stalin's [[Collectivization in the Soviet Union|forced collectivization]].<ref>Vladimir Kuznetsov, [https://www.rubtsovsk.ru/history/ruarea01/010.htm ОТ ПРОДРАЗВЕРСТКИ К ПРОДНАЛОГУ], book chapter from ''Земля Рубцовская: События. Факты. Люди'', 1999</ref>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)