Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Supply and demand
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Graphical representations== ===Supply schedule=== A supply schedule, depicted graphically as a supply curve, is a table that shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity supplied by producers. Under the assumption of [[perfect competition]], supply is determined by [[marginal cost]]: Firms will produce additional output as long as the cost of extra production is less than the market price. A rise in the cost of raw materials would decrease supply, shifting the supply curve to the left because at each possible price a smaller quantity would be supplied. This shift may also be thought of as an upwards shift in the supply curve, because the price must rise for producers to supply a given quantity. A fall in production costs would increase supply, shifting the supply curve to the right and down. Mathematically, a supply curve is represented by a supply function, giving the quantity supplied as a function of its price and as many other variables as desired to better explain quantity supplied. The two most common specifications are: 1) linear supply function, e.g., the slanted line :<math> Q(P) = 3P - 6 </math>, and 2) the constant-[[Elasticity (economics)|elasticity]]<ref>The [[elasticity coefficient]], or often just ''elasticity'', is an important parameter in [[metabolic control analysis]], used to express the local response of an enzyme or other chemical reaction to changes in its environment.</ref> supply function (also called [[isoelastic function|isoelastic]] or log-log or loglinear supply function), e.g., the smooth curve :<math> Q(P) = 5P^{0.5} </math> which can be rewritten as :<math> \log Q(P) = \log 5 + 0.5 \log P </math> The concept of a supply curve assumes that firms are perfect competitors, having no influence over the market price. This is because each point on the supply curve answers the question, "If this firm is faced with this potential price, how much output will it sell?" If a firm has market power—in violation of the perfect competitor model—its decision on how much output to bring to market influences the market price. Thus the firm is not "faced with" any given price, and a more complicated model, e.g., a [[monopoly]] or [[oligopoly]] or [[product differentiation|differentiated-product]] model, should be used. Economists distinguish between the supply curve of an individual firm and the market supply curve. The market supply curve shows the total quantity supplied by all firms, so it is the sum of the quantities supplied by all suppliers at each potential price (that is, the individual firms' supply curves are added horizontally). Economists distinguish between short-run and long-run supply curve. ''Short run'' refers to a time period during which one or more inputs are fixed (typically [[physical capital]]), and the number of firms in the industry is also fixed (if it is a market supply curve). ''Long run'' refers to a time period during which new firms enter or existing firms exit and all inputs can be adjusted fully to any price change. Long-run supply curves are flatter than short-run counterparts (with quantity more sensitive to price, more elastic supply). Common determinants of supply are: # Prices of inputs, including wages # The technology used, [[productivity]] # Firms' expectations about future prices # Number of suppliers (for a market supply curve) ===Demand schedule=== A demand schedule, depicted graphically as a [[demand curve]], represents the amount of a certain [[goods (economics)|good]] that buyers are willing and able to purchase at various prices, assuming all other determinants of demand are held constant, such as income, tastes and preferences, and the prices of [[substitute good|substitute]] and [[complementary good]]s. Generally, consumers will buy an additional unit as long as the marginal value of the extra unit is more than the market price they pay. According to the [[law of demand]], the demand curve is always downward-sloping, meaning that as the price decreases, consumers will buy more of the good. Mathematically, a demand curve is represented by a demand function, giving the quantity demanded as a function of its price and as many other variables as desired to better explain quantity demanded. The two most common specifications are linear demand, e.g., the slanted line :<math> Q(P) = 32 - 2P </math> and the constant-[[Elasticity (economics)|elasticity]] demand function (also called [[isoelastic function|isoelastic]] or log-log or loglinear demand function), e.g., the smooth curve :<math> Q(P) = 3P^{-2} </math> which can be rewritten as :<math> \log Q(P) = \log 3 - 2 \log P </math> As a matter of historical convention, a demand curve is drawn with price on the vertical ''y''-axis and demand on the horizontal ''x''-axis. In keeping with modern convention, a demand curve would instead be drawn with price on the ''x''-axis and demand on the ''y''-axis, because price is the independent variable and demand is the variable that is dependent upon price. Just as the supply curve parallels the [[marginal cost]] curve, the demand curve parallels [[marginal utility]], measured in dollars.<ref>{{cite web|title=Marginal Utility and Demand|url=http://www.amosweb.com/cgi-bin/awb_nav.pl?s=wpd&c=dsp&k=marginal+utility+and+demand|access-date=2007-02-09}}</ref> Consumers will be willing to buy a given quantity of a good, at a given price, if the marginal utility of additional consumption is equal to the [[opportunity cost]] determined by the price, that is, the marginal utility of alternative consumption choices. The demand schedule is defined as the ''willingness'' and ''ability'' of a consumer to purchase a given product at a certain time. The demand curve is generally downward-sloping, but for some goods it is upward-sloping. Two such types of goods have been given definitions and names that are in common use: [[Veblen good]]s, goods which because of fashion or [[signalling]] are more attractive at higher prices, and [[Giffen good]]s, which, by virtue of being [[inferior goods]] that absorb a large part of a consumer's income (e.g., [[Staple food|staples]] such as the classic example of potatoes in Ireland), may see an increase in quantity demanded when the price rises. The reason the law of demand is violated for Giffen goods is that the rise in the price of the good has a strong [[income effect]], sharply reducing the purchasing power of the consumer so that he switches away from luxury goods to the Giffen good, e.g., when the price of potatoes rises, the Irish peasant can no longer afford meat and eats more potatoes to cover for the lost calories. As with the supply curve, the concept of a demand curve requires that the purchaser be a perfect competitor—that is, that the purchaser have no influence over the market price. This is true because each point on the demand curve answers the question, "If buyers are ''faced with'' this potential price, how much of the product will they purchase?" But, if a buyer has market power (that is, the amount he buys influences the price), he is not "faced with" any given price, and we must use a more complicated model, of [[monopsony]]. As with supply curves, economists distinguish between the demand curve for an individual and the demand curve for a market. The market demand curve is obtained by adding the quantities from the individual demand curves at each price. Common determinants of demand are: # Income # Tastes and preferences # Prices of related goods and services # Consumers' expectations about future prices and incomes # Number of potential consumers # Advertising ===History of the curves=== {{multiple image | width1 = 200 | width2 = 360 | width3 = 200 | align = center | footer = Figure 2. Early supply and demand curves | image1 = Cournotdemand.gif | caption1 = Cournot's ''Recherches'' (1838) | image2 = Jenkincurves.gif | caption2 = Jenkin's ''Graphical Representation'' (1870) | image3 = Marshalldemand.gif | caption3 = Marshall's ''Principles'' (1890) }} Since supply and demand can be considered as [[function (mathematics)|functions]] of price they have a natural graphical representation. Demand curves were first drawn by [[Augustin Cournot]] in his {{lang|fr|Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses}} (1838){{snd}}see [[Cournot competition]]. Supply curves were added by [[Fleeming Jenkin]] in ''The Graphical Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand...'' of 1870. Both sorts of curve were popularised by [[Alfred Marshall]] who, in his ''[[Principles of Economics (Marshall book)|Principles of Economics]]'' (1890), chose to represent price{{snd}}normally the independent variable{{snd}}by the vertical axis; a practice which remains common. If supply or demand is a function of other variables besides price, it may be represented by a family of curves (with a change in the other variables constituting a shift between curves) or by a surface in a higher dimensional space.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)