Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Extended producer responsibility
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Implementation== EPR has been implemented in many forms, which may be classified into three major approaches: * Mandatory * Negotiated * Voluntary It is perhaps because of the tendency of economic policy in [[market economy|market-driven economies]] not to interfere with consumers' preferences that the producer-centric representation is the dominant form of viewing the environmental impacts of industrial production: in statistics on energy, emissions, water, etc., impacts are almost always presented as attributes of industries ("on-site" or "direct" allocation) rather than as attributes of the supply chains of products for consumers. On a smaller scale, most existing schemes for [[corporate sustainability]] reporting include only impacts that arise out of operations controlled by the reporting company, and not supply-chain impacts<ref>World Business Council on Sustainable Development a World Resources Institute (2001). The Greenhouse Gas Protocol. Conches-Geneva, Switzerland.</ref> According to this world view, "upstream and downstream [environmental] impacts are ... allocated to their immediate producers. The institutional setting and the different actors' spheres of influence are not reflected".<ref>{{cite journal |author-last1=Spangenberg |author-first1=Joachim H. |author-last2=Lorek |author-first2=Sylvia |date=December 2002 |title=Environmentally sustainable household consumption: from aggregate environmental pressures to priority fields of action |url=https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0921800902002124 |journal=Ecological Economics |language=en |volume=43 |issue=2-3 |pages=127–140 |doi=10.1016/S0921-8009(02)00212-4}}</ref> On the other hand, a number of studies have highlighted that final consumption and affluence, especially in the industrialised world, are the main drivers for the level and growth of environmental pressure. Even though these studies provide a clear incentive for complementing producer-focused environmental policy with some consideration for consumption-related aspects, demand-side measures to address environmental problems are rarely exploited.<ref>{{cite journal |author-last=Princen |author-first=Thomas |date=December 1999 |title=Consumption and environment: some conceptual issues |url=https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0921800999000397 |journal=Ecological Economics |language=en |volume=31 |issue=3 |pages=347–363 |doi=10.1016/S0921-8009(99)00039-7}}</ref> The nexus created by the different views on impacts caused by industrial production is exemplified by several contributions to the discussion about producer or consumer responsibility for [[greenhouse gas emissions]]. Emissions data are reported to the [[IPCC]] as contributions of producing industries located in a particular country rather than as embodiments in products consumed by a particular population, irrespective of productive origin. However, especially for open economies, taking into account the greenhouse gases embodied in internationally traded commodities can have a considerable influence on national greenhouse gas balance sheets. Assuming consumer responsibility, exports have to be subtracted from, and imports added to national greenhouse gas inventories. In Denmark, for example, Munksgaard and Pedersen (2001) report that a significant amount of power and other energy-intensive commodities are traded across Danish borders, and that between 1966 and 1994 the Danish [[foreign trade balance]] in terms of CO<sub>2</sub> developed from a 7 Mt deficit to a 7 Mt surplus, compared to total emissions of approximately 60 Mt.<ref>Munksgaard, Jesper and Pedersen, Klaus Alsted (2001). CO<sub>2</sub> accounts for open economies: producer or consumer responsibility. Energy Policy, 29, pp. 327–334.</ref> In particular, electricity traded between Norway, Sweden and Denmark is subject to large annual fluctuations due to varying rainfall in Norway and Sweden. In wet years Denmark imports [[hydro-electricity]] whereas electricity from coal-fired power plants is exported in dry years. The official Danish emissions inventory includes a correction for electricity trade and thus applies the consumer responsibility principle.<ref>Danish Environmental Protection Agency (1998). Denmark's Second National Communication on Climate Change submitted under the UN FCCC. [http://www.mst.dk Danish Ministry of Environment and Energy] {{Webarchive |url=https://web.archive.org/web/20090908210501/http://www.mst.dk/ |date=2009-09-08}}</ref> Similarly, at the company level, "when adopting the concept of [[eco-efficiency]] and the scope of an [[Natural environment|environmental]] management system stated in for example ISO 14001, it is insufficient to merely report on the carbon dioxide emissions limited to the judicial borders of the company".<ref>{{cite journal |author-last1=Cerin |author-first1=Pontus |author-last2=Karlson |author-first2=Lennart |date=January 2002 |title=Business incentives for sustainability: a property rights approach |url=https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0921800901002750 |journal=Ecological Economics |language=en |volume=40 |issue=1 |pages=13–22 |doi=10.1016/S0921-8009(01)00275-0}}</ref> 7 "Companies must recognise their wider responsibility and manage the entire life-cycle of their products ... Insisting on high environmental standards from suppliers and ensuring that raw materials are extracted or produced in an environmentally conscious way provides a start."<ref>{{cite report |url=https://naturvardsverket.diva-portal.org/smash/get/diva2:1638595/FULLTEXT01.pdf |title=Environmental Strategies in Industry: Turning Business Incentives into Sustainability. Report 5455 |author-last=Cerin |author-first=Pontus |date=2005 |publisher=Swedish Environmental Protection Agency}}</ref> A life-cycle perspective is also taken in EPR frameworks: "Producers of products should bear a significant degree of responsibility (physical and/or financial) not only for the environmental impacts of their products downstream from the treatment and disposal of their product, but also for their upstream activities inherent in the selection of materials and in the design of products."<ref>Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development 2001, p. 21–22</ref> "The major impetus for EPR came from northern European countries in the late 1980s and early 1990s, as they were facing severe landfill shortages. [... As a result,] EPR is generally applied to post-consumer wastes which place increasing physical and financial demands on municipal waste management."<ref>Environment Protection Authority New South Wales 2003, p. 2–4</ref> EPR has rarely been consistently quantified. Moreover, applying conventional [[life cycle assessment]], and assigning environmental impacts to producers and consumers can lead to [[Double counting (accounting)|double-counting]]. Using [[input-output analysis]], researchers have attempted for decades to account for both producers and consumers in an economy in a consistent way. Gallego and Lenzen demonstrate and discuss a method of consistently delineating producers' supply chains, into mutually exclusive and collectively exhaustive responsibilities to be shared by all agents in an economy.<ref>{{cite journal |author-last1=Gallego |author-first1=Blanca |author-last2=Lenzen |author-first2=Manfred |date=December 2005 |title=A consistent input–output formulation of shared producer and consumer responsibility |url=http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/09535310500283492 |journal=Economic Systems Research |language=en |volume=17 |issue=4 |pages=365–391 |doi=10.1080/09535310500283492 |issn=0953-5314}}</ref> Their method is an approach to allocating responsibility across agents in a fully inter-connected circular system. Upstream and downstream environmental impacts are shared between all agents of a supply chain—producers and consumers.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)