Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Arrow–Debreu model
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== Imposing an artificial restriction === The functions <math> D^i(p), S^j(p)</math> are not necessarily well-defined for all price vectors <math>p</math>. For example, if producer 1 is capable of transforming <math>t</math> units of commodity 1 into <math>\sqrt{(t+1)^2-1}</math> units of commodity 2, and we have <math>p_1 / p_2 < 1</math>, then the producer can create plans with infinite profit, thus <math>\Pi^j(p) = +\infty</math>, and <math>S^j(p)</math> is undefined. Consequently, we define "'''restricted market'''" to be the same market, except there is a universal upper bound <math>C</math>, such that every producer is required to use a production plan <math>\|y^j\| \leq C</math>. Each household is required to use a consumption plan <math>\|x^i\| \leq C</math>. Denote the corresponding quantities on the restricted market with a tilde. So, for example, <math>\tilde Z(p)</math> is the excess demand function on the restricted market.<ref>The restricted market technique is described in (Starr 2011), Section 18.2. The technique was used in the original publication by Arrow and Debreu (1954).</ref> <math>C</math> is chosen to be "large enough" for the economy so that the restriction is not in effect under equilibrium conditions (see next section). In detail, <math>C</math> is chosen to be large enough such that: * For any consumption plan <math>x</math> such that <math>x \succeq 0, \|x\| = C</math>, the plan is so "extravagant" that even if all the producers coordinate, they would still fall short of meeting the demand. * For any list of production plans for the economy <math>(y^j\in PPS^j)_{j\in J}</math>, if <math>\sum_{j\in J} y^j + r \succeq 0</math>, then <math>\|y^j\| < C</math>for each <math>j\in J</math>. In other words, for any attainable production plan under the given endowment <math>r</math>, each producer's individual production plan must lie strictly within the restriction. Each requirement is satisfiable. * Define the set of '''attainable aggregate production plans''' to be <math>PPS_r = \left\{\sum_{j\in J} y^j : y^j \in PPS^j \text{ for each } j\in J, \text{ and }\sum_{j\in J} y^j + r \succeq 0\right\}</math>, then under the assumptions for the producers given above (especially the "no arbitrarily large free lunch" assumption), <math>PPS_r</math> is bounded for any <math>r \succeq 0</math> (proof omitted). Thus the first requirement is satisfiable. * Define the set of '''attainable individual production plans''' to be <math>PPS_r^j := \{y^j \in PPS^j: y^j\text{ is a part of some attainable production plan under endowment }r\}</math>then under the assumptions for the producers given above (especially the "no arbitrarily large transformations" assumption), <math>PPS_r^j</math> is bounded for any <math>j\in J, r \succeq 0</math> (proof omitted). Thus the second requirement is satisfiable. The two requirements together imply that the restriction is not a real restriction when the production plans and consumption plans are "[[Interior solution (optimization)|interior]]" to the restriction. * At any price vector <math>p</math>, if <math>\|\tilde S^j(p)\| < C</math>, then <math>S^j(p) </math> exists and is equal to <math>\tilde S^j(p) </math>. In other words, if the production plan of a restricted producer is interior to the artificial restriction, then the unrestricted producer would choose the same production plan. This is proved by exploiting the second requirement on <math>C</math>. * If all <math>S^j(p) = \tilde S^j(p)</math>, then the restricted and unrestricted households have the same budget. Now, if we also have <math>\|\tilde D^i(p)\| < C</math>, then <math>D^i(p) </math> exists and is equal to <math>\tilde D^i(p) </math>. In other words, if the consumption plan of a restricted household is interior to the artificial restriction, then the unrestricted household would choose the same consumption plan. This is proved by exploiting the first requirement on <math>C</math>. These two propositions imply that equilibria for the restricted market are equilibria for the unrestricted market:{{Math theorem | name = Theorem | note = | math_statement =If <math>p</math> is an equilibrium price vector for the restricted market, then it is also an equilibrium price vector for the unrestricted market. Furthermore, we have <math>\tilde D^i(p) = D^i(p), \tilde S^j(p) = S^j(p)</math>. }}
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)