Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Modern portfolio theory
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Asset pricing== The above analysis describes optimal behavior of an individual investor. [[Asset pricing|Asset pricing theory]] builds on this analysis, allowing MPT to derive the required expected return for a correctly priced asset in this context. Intuitively (in a [[perfect market]] with [[rational investor]]s), if a security was expensive relative to others - i.e. too much risk for the price - demand would fall and its price would drop correspondingly; if cheap, demand and price would increase likewise. This would continue until all such adjustments had ceased - a state of "[[market equilibrium]]". In this equilibrium, relative supplies will equal relative demands: given the relationship of price with supply and demand, since the risk-to-reward ratio is "identical" across all securities, proportions of each security in any fully-diversified portfolio would correspondingly be the same as in the overall market. More formally, then, since everyone holds the risky assets in identical proportions to each other — namely in the proportions given by the tangency portfolio — in [[market equilibrium]] the risky assets' prices, and therefore their expected returns, will adjust so that the ratios in the tangency portfolio are the same as the ratios in which the risky assets are supplied to the market.<ref name="Bollerslev"/> The result for expected return then follows, as below. ===Systematic risk and specific risk=== {{unreferenced section|date=April 2021}} Specific risk is the risk associated with individual assets - within a portfolio these risks can be reduced through diversification (specific risks "cancel out"). Specific risk is also called diversifiable, unique, unsystematic, or idiosyncratic risk. [[Systematic risk]] (a.k.a. portfolio risk or market risk) refers to the risk common to all securities—except for [[short (finance)|selling short]] as noted below, systematic risk cannot be diversified away (within one market). Within the market portfolio, asset specific risk will be diversified away to the extent possible. Systematic risk is therefore equated with the risk (standard deviation) of the market portfolio. Since a security will be purchased only if it improves the risk-expected return characteristics of the market portfolio, the relevant measure of the risk of a security is the risk it adds to the market portfolio, and not its risk in isolation. In this context, the volatility of the asset, and its correlation with the market portfolio, are historically observed and are therefore given. (There are several approaches to asset pricing that attempt to price assets by modelling the stochastic properties of the moments of assets' returns - these are broadly referred to as conditional asset pricing models.) Systematic risks within one market can be managed through a strategy of using both long and short positions within one portfolio, creating a "market neutral" portfolio. Market neutral portfolios, therefore, will be uncorrelated with broader market indices. ===Capital asset pricing model=== {{main article|Capital asset pricing model}} <!-- {{Unreferenced section|date=June 2023}} --> The asset return depends on the amount paid for the asset today. The price paid must ensure that the market portfolio's risk / return characteristics improve when the asset is added to it. The [[Capital asset pricing model|CAPM]] is a model that derives the theoretical required expected return (i.e., discount rate) for an asset in a market, given the risk-free rate available to investors and the risk of the market as a whole. The CAPM is usually expressed: :<math> \operatorname{E}(R_i) = R_f + \beta_i (\operatorname{E}(R_m) - R_f) </math> *β, [[Beta (finance)|Beta]], is the measure of asset sensitivity to a movement in the overall market; Beta is usually found via [[regression analysis|regression]] on historical data. Betas exceeding one signify more than average "riskiness" in the sense of the asset's contribution to overall portfolio risk; betas below one indicate a lower than average risk contribution. *<math> (\operatorname{E}(R_m) - R_f) </math> is the market premium, the expected excess return of the market portfolio's expected return over the risk-free rate. A derivation <ref name="Bollerslev">See, e.g., [[Tim Bollerslev]] (2019). [http://public.econ.duke.edu/~boller/Econ.471-571.F19/Lec3_471-571_F19.pdf "Risk and Return in Equilibrium: The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)"]</ref> is as follows: <blockquote style="background: 1; border: 1px solid black; padding: 1em;"> (1) The incremental impact on risk and expected return when an additional risky asset, '''a''', is added to the market portfolio, '''m''', follows from the formulae for a two-asset portfolio. These results are used to derive the asset-appropriate discount rate. *Updated portfolio risk = <math> (w_m^2 \sigma_m ^2 + [ w_a^2 \sigma_a^2 + 2 w_m w_a \rho_{am} \sigma_a \sigma_m] ) </math> ::Hence, risk added to portfolio = <math> [ w_a^2 \sigma_a^2 + 2 w_m w_a \rho_{am} \sigma_a \sigma_m] </math> ::but since the weight of the asset will be very low re. the overall market, <math> w_a^2 \approx 0 </math> ::i.e. additional risk = <math> [ 2 w_m w_a \rho_{am} \sigma_a \sigma_m] \quad </math> *Updated expected return = <math> ( w_m \operatorname{E}(R_m) + [ w_a \operatorname{E}(R_a) ] ) </math> ::Hence additional expected return = <math> [ w_a \operatorname{E}(R_a) ] </math> (2) If an asset, '''a''', is correctly priced, the improvement for an investor in her risk-to-expected return ratio achieved by adding it to the market portfolio, '''m''', will at least (in equilibrium, exactly) match the gains of spending that money on an increased stake in the market portfolio. The assumption is that the investor will purchase the asset with funds borrowed at the risk-free rate, '''<math>R_f</math>'''; this is rational if <math> \operatorname{E}(R_a) > R_f </math>. :Thus: <math> [ w_a ( \operatorname{E}(R_a) - R_f ) ] / [2 w_m w_a \rho_{am} \sigma_a \sigma_m] = [ w_a ( \operatorname{E}(R_m) - R_f ) ] / [2 w_m w_a \sigma_m \sigma_m ] </math> :i.e.: <math> [\operatorname{E}(R_a) ] = R_f + [\operatorname{E}(R_m) - R_f] * [ \rho_{am} \sigma_a \sigma_m] / [ \sigma_m \sigma_m ] </math> :i.e.: <math> [\operatorname{E}(R_a) ] = R_f + [\operatorname{E}(R_m) - R_f] * [\sigma_{am}] / [ \sigma_{mm}] </math> {{resize|75%|([[Covariance and correlation|since]] <math>\rho_{XY} = \sigma_{XY} / (\sigma_X \sigma_Y) </math>)}} : <math>[\sigma_{am}] / [ \sigma_{mm}] \quad</math> is the "beta", <math>\beta</math> return mentioned — the [[covariance]] between the asset's return and the market's return divided by the variance of the market return — i.e. the sensitivity of the asset price to movement in the market portfolio's value (see also {{slink|Beta (finance)#Adding an asset to the market portfolio}}). </blockquote> This equation can be [[estimation theory|estimated]] statistically using the following [[regression analysis|regression]] equation: :<math>\mathrm{SCL} : R_{i,t} - R_{f} = \alpha_i + \beta_i\, ( R_{M,t} - R_{f} ) + \epsilon_{i,t} \frac{}{}</math> where α<sub>''i''</sub> is called the asset's [[Alpha (finance)|alpha]], β<sub>''i''</sub> is the asset's [[beta coefficient]] and SCL is the [[security characteristic line]]. Once an asset's expected return, <math> E(R_i) </math>, is calculated using CAPM, the future [[cash flow]]s of the asset can be [[discounted]] to their [[present value]] using this rate to establish the correct price for the asset. A riskier stock will have a higher beta and will be discounted at a higher rate; less sensitive stocks will have lower betas and be discounted at a lower rate. In theory, an asset is correctly priced when its observed price is the same as its value calculated using the CAPM derived discount rate. If the observed price is higher than the valuation, then the asset is overvalued; it is undervalued for a too low price.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)