Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Input–output model
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===The Leontief IO model with capital formation endogenized === The IO model discussed above is static because it does not describe the evolution of the economy over time: it does not include different time periods. Dynamic Leontief models are obtained by endogenizing the formation of capital stock over time. Denote by <math>y^I</math>the vector of capital formation, with <math>y^I_i</math> its <math>i</math>th element, and by <math>I_{ij}(t)</math> the amount of capital good <math>i</math> (for example, a blade) used in sector <math>j</math> ( for example, wind power generation), for investment at time <math>t</math>. We then have <math> y^I_i(t) = \sum_j I_{ij}(t) </math> We assume that it takes one year for investment in plant and equipment to become productive capacity. Denoting by <math>K_{ij}(t)</math> the stock of <math>i</math> at the beginning of time <math>t</math>, and by <math>\delta \in (0,1]</math> the rate of depreciation, we then have: {{NumBlk|::| <math> K_{ij}(t+1) = I_{ij}(t) + (1-\delta_{ij})K_{ij}(t) </math> |{{EquationRef|2}}}} Here, <math>\delta_{ij}K_{ij}(t)</math> refers to the amount of capital stock that is used up in year <math>t</math>. Denote by <math>\bar{x}_j(t)</math> the productive capacity in <math>t</math>, and assume the following proportionalty between <math>K_{ij}(t)</math> and <math>\bar{x}_j(t)</math>: {{NumBlk|::| <math> K_{ij}(t) = b_{ij}\bar{x}_j(t) </math> |{{EquationRef|3}}}} The matrix <math>B=[b_{ij}]</math> is called the capital coefficient matrix. From ({{EquationNote|2}}) and ({{EquationNote|3}}), we obtain the following expression for <math>y^I</math>: <math> y^I(t) = B\bar{x}(t+1) + (\delta - I)\bar{x}(t) </math> Assuming that the productive capacity is always fully utilized, we obtain the following expression for ({{EquationNote|1}}) with endogenized capital formation: <math> x(t) = Ax(t)+Bx(t+1)+ (\delta-I)Bx(t) + y^o(t), </math> where <math>y^o</math> stands for the items of final demand other than <math>y^I</math>. Rearranged, we have <math> \begin{align} Bx(t+1) &= (I-A + (I-\delta)B)x(t) - y^o(t)\\ &= (I - \bar{A} + B)x(t) - y^o(t) \end{align} </math> wehere <math>\bar{A}=A + \delta B</math>. If <math>B</math> is non-singular, this model could be solved for <math>x(t+1)</math> for given <math>x(t)</math> and <math>y^o(t)</math>: <math> x(t+1) = [I + B^{-1}(I- \bar{A})]x(t) - B^{-1}y^o(t) </math> This is the '''Leontief dynamic forward-looking model'''<ref>Wassily Leontief, Dynamic Analysis, Ch.3. In: W. Leontief et al.(eds.) Studies in the Structure of the American Economy. 1953, New York, Oxford University Press, 53–90.</ref> A caveat to this model is that <math>B</math> will, in general, be singular, and the above formulation cannot be obtained. This is because some products, such as energy items, are not used as capital goods, and the corresponding rows of the matrix <math>B</math> will be zeros. This fact has prompted some researchers to consolidate the sectors until the non-singularity of <math>B</math> is achieved, at the cost of sector resolution.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Jorgenson |first=Dale W. |date=February 1961 |title=Stability of a Dynamic Input-Output System |url=https://doi.org/10.2307/2295708 |journal=The Review of Economic Studies |volume=28 |issue=2 |pages=105–116 |doi=10.2307/2295708 |jstor=2295708 |issn=0034-6527|url-access=subscription }}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Tsukui |first=Jinkichi |date=1968 |title=Application of a Turnpike Theorem to Planning for Efficient Accumulation: An Example for Japan |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1909611 |journal=Econometrica |volume=36 |issue=1 |pages=172–186 |doi=10.2307/1909611 |jstor=1909611 |issn=0012-9682|url-access=subscription }}</ref> Apart from this feature, many studies have found that the outcomes obtained for this forward-looking model invariably lead to unrealistic and widely fluctuating results that lack economic interpretation.<ref>Dorfman, Robert, Paul Anthony Samuelson, and Robert M. Solow. ''Linear programming and economic analysis''. RAND Corporation, 1958. Chapter 11. </ref><ref>Jinkichi Tsukui, (1961) On a Theorem of Relative Stability. International Economic Review, 2, 229–230.</ref><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Bródy |first=A. |date=January 1995 |title=Truncation and Spectrum of the Dynamic Inverse |url=http://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/09535319500000022 |journal=Economic Systems Research |language=en |volume=7 |issue=3 |pages=235–248 |doi=10.1080/09535319500000022 |issn=0953-5314|url-access=subscription }}</ref> This has resulted in a gradual decline in interest in the model after the 1970s, although there is a recent increase in interest within the context of disaster analysis.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Steenge |first1=Albert E. |last2=Reyes |first2=Rachel C. |date=2020-10-01 |title=Return of the capital coefficients matrix |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/09535314.2020.1731682 |journal=Economic Systems Research |language=en |volume=32 |issue=4 |pages=439–450 |doi=10.1080/09535314.2020.1731682 |issn=0953-5314}}</ref>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)