Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Mergers and acquisitions
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===Other types=== On average and across the most commonly studied variables, acquiring firms' financial performance does not positively change as a function of their acquisition activity.<ref>{{cite journal |last=King |first=D. R. |author2=Dalton, D. R. |author3=Daily, C. M. |author4= Covin, J. G. |year=2004 |title=Meta-analyses of Post-acquisition Performance: Indications of Unidentified Moderators |journal=Strategic Management Journal |volume=25 |issue=2 |pages=187β200 |doi=10.1002/smj.371 |s2cid=36682294 |url= https://epublications.marquette.edu/mgmt_fac/99|url-access=subscription }}</ref> Therefore, additional motives for merger and acquisition that may not add shareholder value include: * Diversification: While this may hedge a company against a downturn in an individual industry it fails to deliver value, since it is possible for individual shareholders to achieve the same hedge by diversifying their portfolios at a much lower cost than those associated with a merger. (In his book ''One Up on Wall Street'', Peter Lynch termed this "diworseification".)<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Amihud |first1=Yakov |last2=Baruch |first2=Lev |title=Risk Reduction as a Managerial Motive for Conglomerate Mergers |journal=The Bell Journal of Economics |date=1981 |volume=12 |issue=2 |pages=605 |doi=10.2307/3003575 |url=https://www.researchgate.net/publication/24047961|jstor=3003575 }}</ref> *[[Managerial hubris|Manager's hubris]]: manager's overconfidence about expected synergies from M&A which results in overpayment for the target company.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Roll |first1=Richard |title=The Hubris Hypothesis of Corporate Takeovers |journal=The Journal of Business |date=1986 |volume=59 |issue=2 |pages=197β216 |jstor=2353017 |doi=10.1086/296325 }}</ref> The effect of manager's overconfidence on M&A has been shown to hold both for CEOs<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Malmendier |first1=Ulrike |last2=Tate |first2=Geoffrey |title=Who makes acquisitions? CEO overconfidence and the market's reaction |journal=[[Journal of Financial Economics]] |date=2008 |volume=89 |issue=1 |pages=20β43 |url=https://econpapers.repec.org/article/eeejfinec/v_3a89_3ay_3a2008_3ai_3a1_3ap_3a20-43.htm|doi=10.1016/j.jfineco.2007.07.002 |s2cid=12354773 }}</ref> and board directors.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Twardawski |first1=Torsten |last2=Kind |first2=Axel |title=Board overconfidence in mergers and acquisitions |journal=[[Journal of Business Research]] |date=2023 |volume=165 |issue=1 |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0148296323003843|doi=10.1016/j.jbusres.2023.114026|url-access=subscription }}</ref> *Empire-building: Managers have larger companies to manage and hence more power. *Manager's compensation: In the past, certain executive management teams had their payout based on the total amount of profit of the company, instead of the profit per share, which would give the team a [[perverse incentive]] to buy companies to increase the total profit while decreasing the profit per share (which hurts the owners of the company, the shareholders).
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)