Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Long Depression
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Interpretations== Most economic historians see this period as negative for the most industrial nations.{{citation needed|date=January 2012}} Many argue that most of the stagnation was caused by a monetary contraction caused by abandonment of the [[bimetallic standard]], in favor of a new fiat [[gold standard]], starting with the [[Coinage Act of 1873]].{{citation needed|date=January 2012}} Other economic historians have complained about the characterization of this period as a "depression" because of conflicting economic statistics that cast doubt on this interpretation. They note it saw a relatively large expansion of industry, of railroads, of physical output, of net national product, and of real per capita income. As economists [[Milton Friedman]] and [[Anna J. Schwartz]] have noted, the decade from 1869 to 1879 saw a growth of 3 percent per year in money national product, an outstanding real national product growth of 6.8 percent per year, and a rise of 4.5 percent per year in real product per capita. Even the alleged "monetary contraction" never took place, the money supply increasing by 2.7 percent per year. From 1873 through 1878, before another spurt of monetary expansion, the total supply of bank money rose from $1.964 billion to $2.221 billion, a rise of 13.1 percent, or 2.6 percent per year. In short, it was a modest but definite rise, not a contraction.<ref name="Friedman_Schwartz">Friedman, Schwartz. A Monetary History of the United States: 1867β1960.</ref> Although per-capita nominal income declined very gradually from 1873 to 1879, that decline was more than offset by a gradual increase over the course of the next 17 years. Furthermore, real per capita income either stayed approximately constant (1873β1880; 1883β1885) or rose (1881β1882; 1886β1896), so the average consumer appears to have been considerably better off at the end of the "depression" than before. Studies of other countries where prices also tumbled, including the United States, Germany, France, and Italy, reported more markedly positive trends in both nominal and real per capita income figures. Profits generally were also not adversely affected by deflation, although they declined (particularly in the UK) in industries struggling against superior, foreign competition. Furthermore, some economists argue a falling general price level is not inherently harmful to an economy and cite the economic growth of the period as evidence.<ref name="Rothbard_1873">Murray N. Rothbard. [https://mises.org/books/historyofmoney.pdf "A History of Money and Banking in the United States: The Colonial Era to World War II"] (pdf), The War of 1812 and its Aftermath, pp. 145, 153β156.</ref> As economist [[Murray Rothbard]] has stated: <blockquote>Unfortunately, most historians and economists are conditioned to believe that steadily and sharply falling prices must result in depression: hence their amazement at the obvious prosperity and economic growth during this era. For they have overlooked the fact that in the natural course of events, when government and the banking system do not increase the money supply very rapidly, freemarket capitalism will result in an increase of production and economic growth so great as to swamp the increase of money supply. Prices will fall, and the consequences will be not depression or stagnation, but prosperity (since costs are falling, too), economic growth, and the spread of the increased living standard to all the consumers.<ref name="Rothbard_1873"/></blockquote> Accompanying the overall growth in real prosperity was a marked shift in consumption from necessities to luxuries: by 1885, "more houses were being built, twice as much tea was being consumed, and even the working classes were eating imported meat, oranges, and dairy produce in quantities unprecedented". The change in working class incomes and tastes was symbolized by "the spectacular development of the department store and the chain store". <blockquote>Prices certainly fell, but almost every other index of economic activity β output of coal and pig iron, tonnage of ships built, consumption of raw wool and cotton, import and export figures, shipping entries and clearances, railway freight clearances, joint-stock company formations, trading profits, consumption per head of wheat, meat, tea, beer, and tobacco β all of these showed an upward trend.<ref name="Musson">A.E. Musson. [http://journals.cambridge.org/action/displayAbstract?fromPage=online&aid=7583296 "The Great Depression in Britain, 1873β1896: a Reappraisal"], ''The Journal of Economic History'' (1959), 19: 199β228</ref></blockquote> A large part at least of the deflation commencing in the 1870s was a reflection of unprecedented advances in factory productivity. Real unit production costs for most final goods dropped steadily throughout the 19th century and especially from 1873 to 1896. At no previous time had there been an equivalent "harvest of technological advances... so general in their application and so radical in their implications". That is why, notwithstanding the dire predictions of many eminent economists, the UK did not end up paralyzed by strikes and lockouts. Falling prices did not mean falling money wages. Instead of inspiring large numbers of workers to go on strike, falling prices were inspiring them to go shopping.<ref name="Selgin_Zero">George Selgin. [https://mises.org/resources/5301/Less-than-Zero-The-Case-for-a-Falling-Price-Level-in-a-Growing-Economy "Less Than Zero β The Case for a Falling Price Level in a Growing Economy"], ''The Institute of Economic Affairs'', 1997, pp. 49β53. Referenced 2011-01-15.</ref>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)