Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Additional-member system
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== Counting votes and allocating seats === The first vote is used to elect a member from their constituency under the [[First-past-the-post voting|"first-past-the-post"]] first-preference plurality (FPP) system (i.e. in the constituency, the candidate with the most votes takes the seat). The second vote is used to determine how many additional seats a party may get, which is based on how many seats a party should get in total. Parties receive additional seats to match the vote shares they received as close as possible, making the legislature more representative of voters' preferences. In the model of the AMS as used in the United Kingdom, the regional seats are divided using a [[D'Hondt method]]. However, the number of seats already won in the local constituencies is taken into account in the calculations for the list seats,<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.parliament.uk/about/how/elections-and-voting/voting-systems/|title=Voting systems in the UK - UK Parliament}}</ref> and the first average taken in account for each party follows the number of FPTP seats won. For example, if a party won 5 constituency seats, then the first D'Hondt divisor taken for that party would be 6 (5 seats + 1), not 1. In [[South Korea]], which uses the [[largest remainder method]], constituency seats are taken into account by subtracting the number of constituency seats that the party won from the number of seats initially won by the party proportionally (over all seats).<ref>{{Cite web|date=2020-04-15|title=How Does South Korea's New Election System Work?|url=https://keia.org/the-peninsula/how-does-south-koreas-new-election-system-work/|access-date=2021-11-20|website=Korea Economic Institute of America|language=en}}</ref> ==== Example ==== In a 100 seat assembly 70 members are elected in single-member constituencies. Because the system generally favours the largest party and those parties/candidate that are strong in a particular region, the total result of the constituency (FPP) elections can be very disproportional. In this example, the party with a [[Plurality (voting)|plurality]] in the popular vote (party A) won a majority of all seats (54), while the second largest party (B) only won 11 districts. One of the two smaller parties (party C) won no districts, despite having 13% support nationwide, but a smaller (regional) party with only 3% nationally did get 5 of their candidates elected, as their voters were concentrated in those constituencies. {| class="wikitable" ! colspan="2" |Party !Popular vote (%) !Constituency seats !Additional seats !Total seats !Constituency seats |- | style="background:#D10000" | |Party A |'''43%''' |'''54''' | ? | ? | rowspan="5" |[[File:AMS fptp seats.svg|frameless]] |- | style="background:#0008A5" | |Party B |'''41%''' |'''11''' | ? | ? |- | style="background:#03AA00" | |Party C |'''13%''' |'''0''' | ? | ? |- | style="background:#820084" | |Party D |'''3%''' |'''5''' | ? | ? |- | |TOTAL |100% |70 |30 |100 |} In the example, additional seats are assigned on a nationwide level. Parties A and D are already overrepresented, so they are not entitled to additional seats. Parties B and C receive top-up seats, as there are only 30, this is not enough to make the results proportional. {| class="wikitable" ! colspan="2" |Party !Popular vote (%) !Constituency seats !Additional seats !Total seats !Overhang seats !Seats deficit !Additional seats !Total seats |- | style="background:#D10000" | |Party A |43% |54 |'''0''' |'''54''' | +11 | | rowspan="5" |[[File:AMS additional seats.svg|frameless]] | rowspan="5" |[[File:AMS total seats.svg|frameless]] |- | style="background:#0008A5" | |Party B |41% |11 |'''23''' |'''34''' | |7 |- | style="background:#03AA00" | |Party C |13% |0 |'''7''' |'''7''' | |6 |- | style="background:#820084" | |Party D |3% |5 |'''0''' |'''5''' | +2 | |- | |TOTAL |100% |70 |30 |100 |13 | |} ==== Compared to similar systems ==== If the 30 additional seats in the example were allocated independently by list-PR the system would be called [[parallel voting]] or a ''supplementary member'' system. This would be a [[Mixed-member majoritarian representation|mixed-member majoritarian]] system (MMM), under which even party A received additional seats, even though it is overrepresented even without getting any. Some systems called [[Mixed-member proportional representation|mixed-member proportional systems]] (MMP), like the ones used for electing the national parliament [[New Zealand]], at least partially compensate for [[overhang seats]] as well, by adding back that many seats to the assembly if needed, but this is not a perfect correction for the disproportionality. In [[Germany]] formerly even [[Leveling seat|more seats]] were adding to the Bundestag, to get fully proportional results, but as per the latest reform, parties simply may not keep overhang seats, meaning they might not be able to keep all constituency seats they "won" in. In this example, the assembly size would be increased by 13 seats to compensate for parties B and C's seat deficits under the New Zealand type 'MMP', and by 65 (which allows parties A, B and C to receive more seats) under a flexible amount of additional leveling seats. The additional member system might provide [[proportional representation]] when there are no overhang seats that would need to be compensated; in this case it would have the same outcome as other 'MMP' systems, if the results of the FPTP elections were completely proportional (which is almost never the case in reality). If decoy lists and tactical voting were used (see below), the results under the AMS would be the same as under parallel voting. In all other cases the AMS is more proportional than parallel voting, but sometimes less proportional than 'MMP' in New Zealand. {| class="wikitable" ! colspan="4" rowspan="3" | ! colspan="2" rowspan="2" |Constituency seats only ([[First-past-the-post voting|FPTP]]) ! colspan="2" |[[Mixed-member majoritarian representation|Mixed-member majoritarian]] ! colspan="6" |Broadly [[Mixed-member proportional representation|mixed-member proportional]] type of system (MMP) |- ! colspan="2" |[[Parallel voting]] (supplementary member system) ! colspan="2" |Additional member system (AMS) ! colspan="2" | Overhang seats re-added ! colspan="2" | True MMP (with leveling seats) |- | colspan="2" |[[File:AMS fptp seats.svg|frameless]] | colspan="2" |[[File:AMS example parallel total seats.svg|frameless]] | colspan="2" |[[File:AMS total seats.svg|frameless]] | colspan="2" |[[File:AMS example MMP overhang only total seats.svg|frameless]] | colspan="2" |[[File:AMS example MMP total seats.svg|frameless]] |- ! colspan="2" |Party !Popular vote (%) !Constitu­encies won !Seats !Share (%) !Seats !Share (%) !Seats !Share (%) !Seats !Share (%) !Seats !Share (%) |- | style="background:#D10000" | |Party A |43% |54 |54 |77% |67 (54+13) |67% |54 (54+0) |54% |54 (54+0+0) |48% |71 (54+0+17) |43% |- | style="background:#0008A5" | |Party B |41% |11 |11 |16% |24 (11+13) |24% |34 (11+23) |34% |41 (11+23+7) |36% |68 (11+23+34) |41% |- | style="background:#03AA00" | |Party C |13% |0 |0 |0% |3 (0+3) |3% |7 (0+7) |7% |13 (0+7+6) |12% |21 (0+7+14) |13% |- | style="background:#820084" | |Party D |3% |5 |5 |7% |5 (5+0) |5% |5 (5+0) |5% |5 (5+0+0) |4% |5 (5+0+0) |3% |- | |TOTAL |100% |70 |70 |100% |100 (70+30) |100% |100 (70+30) |100% |113 (70+30+13) |100% |165 (70+30+65) |100% |- | colspan="4" |Index of disproportionality ([[Gallagher index|Gallagher]]) | colspan="2" |31.55 (highly disproportional) | colspan="2" |22.01 (disproportional) | colspan="2" |10.25 (moderately disproportional) | colspan="2" |4.97 (considered proportional) | colspan="2" |0.25 (highly proportional) |- | colspan="4" |'''Method used''' | colspan="2" |Only first-past-the-post | colspan="2" |Independent PR tier | colspan="2" |Fixed number of compensatory seats | colspan="2" |Number of (extra) leveling seats = number of overhang seats | colspan="2" |As many leveling seats as needed |- | colspan="4" |'''This type of system used in''' | colspan="2" |United Kingdom, among others | colspan="2" |Russia, among others | colspan="2" |Scotland, London | colspan="2" |New Zealand, Germany (until 2009) | colspan="2" |Germany (2013, 2017) |}
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)