Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Inflation
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==== New Keynesians ==== Events during the 1970s proved Milton Friedman and other critics of the traditional Phillips curve right: The relation between the inflation rate and the unemployment rate broke down. Eventually, a consensus was established that the break-down was due to agents changing their inflation expectations, confirming Friedman's theory. As a consequence, the notion of a [[natural rate of unemployment]] (alternatively called the structural rate of unemployment) was accepted by most economists, meaning that there is a specific level of unemployment that is compatible with stable inflation. [[Stabilization policy]] must therefore try to steer economic activity so that the actual unemployment rate converges towards that level.<ref name=Blanchard/>{{rp|176β189}} The trade-off between the [[unemployment rate]] and inflation implied by Phillips thus holds in the short term, but not in the long term.<ref>Chang, R. (1997) [https://www.frbatlanta.org/filelegacydocs/ACFC7.pdf "Is Low Unemployment Inflationary?"] {{webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20131113212953/https://www.frbatlanta.org/filelegacydocs/ACFC7.pdf|date=November 13, 2013}} ''Federal Reserve Bank of Atlanta Economic Review'' 1Q97: 4β13.</ref> Also the [[1970s energy crisis|oil crises of the 1970s]] causing at the same time rising unemployment and rising inflation (i.e. [[stagflation]]) led to a broad recognition by economists that [[supply shock]]s could independently affect inflation.<ref name=parkin/><ref name=Blanchard/>{{rp|529}} During the 1980s a group of researchers named [[New Keynesian economics|new Keynesians]] emerged who accepted many originally non-Keynesian concepts like the importance of monetary policy, the existence of a natural level of unemployment and the incorporation of rational expectations formation as a reasonable benchmark. At the same time they believed, like Keynes did, that various [[market imperfection]]s in different markets like labour markets and financial markets were also important to study to understand both inflation generation and [[business cycle]]s.<ref name=Blanchard/>{{rp|533β534}} During the 1980s and 1990s, there were often heated intellectual debates between new Keynesians and new classicals, but by the 2000s, a synthesis gradually emerged. The result has been called the ''new Keynesian model'',<ref name=Blanchard/>{{rp|535}} the "[[new neoclassical synthesis]]"<ref name=Goodfriend>{{cite journal |last1=Goodfriend |first1=Marvin |title=How the World Achieved Consensus on Monetary Policy |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |date=1 November 2007 |volume=21 |issue=4 |pages=47β68 |doi=10.1257/jep.21.4.47|s2cid=56338417 |doi-access=free }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Woodford |first1=Michael |title=Convergence in Macroeconomics: Elements of the New Synthesis |journal=American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics |date=1 January 2009 |volume=1 |issue=1 |pages=267β279 |doi=10.1257/mac.1.1.267}}</ref> or simply the "new consensus" model.<ref name=Goodfriend/>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)