Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Time preference
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== Climate change === The discount rate is particularly important in the study of climate change. Economist Thomas Schelling argued that climate change is an intergenerational discounting problem, where we are essentially deciding how to distribute utility between the current and future generations.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Schelling |first=Thomas C |date=1995-04-01 |title=Intergenerational discounting |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/0301421595901643 |journal=Energy Policy |series=Integrated assessments of mitigation, impacts and adaptation to climate change |volume=23 |issue=4 |pages=395β401 |doi=10.1016/0301-4215(95)90164-3 |issn=0301-4215|url-access=subscription }}</ref> Crucially, he also argues that we need to also consider other ways in which we can increase the well being of underdeveloped countries both now and in the future. Climate abatement techniques, viewed through this lens, need to be weighed against other wealth redistributions, such as direct payments or subsidies for other goods and industries. One of the first papers to address this issue was Frank Ramseyβs βA Mathematical Theory of Saving.β In it, he calculates the amount which a nation should save to protect future generations. He does this by trying to maximize the utility of all generations cumulatively.<ref name="Ramsey 1928 543β559">{{Cite journal |last=Ramsey |first=F. P. |date=1928 |title=A Mathematical Theory of Saving |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2224098 |journal=The Economic Journal |volume=38 |issue=152 |pages=543β559 |doi=10.2307/2224098 |jstor=2224098 |issn=0013-0133|url-access=subscription }}</ref> In solving this maximization problem, we get an equation of the form<ref name="Ramsey 1928 543β559"/> <math>r = \delta + \eta g</math> Here, <math>r</math> is the rate of time preference, or the discount rate. It is the sum of the pure rate of time preference (<math>\delta</math>) and the growth rate of per capita consumption (<math>g</math>), adjusted by the factor (<math>\eta</math>), which represents the impact of economic growth on the discount rate. The next big finding on the climate discount rate was the Stern Review.<ref>{{Cite web |title=The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review |url=https://www.lse.ac.uk/GranthamInstitute/publication/the-economics-of-climate-change-the-stern-review/ |access-date=2024-11-18 |website=Grantham Research Institute on climate change and the environment |language=en-GB}}</ref> It was a report commissioned by the UK government in 2006 on the state of climate change. Major finding of the report is that urgent action is needed to avert the worst impacts of climate change; much more urgent than previously thought. This is due to his estimation of the discount rate. In the report, Stern sets the Ramsey parameters to <math>\delta = .1%</math>, <math>\eta = 1</math> and <math>g=1.3%</math> , meaning <math>r=1.4%</math> . With a discount rate this low, meaning future generations are almost equally as valued, this means that society needs to drastically reduce consumption. There was push back against this idea, most notably from economist William Nordhaus. He wrote several papers reviewing the Stern Report and the assumptions in it. He argues that the near zero rate of time preference (<math>\delta = .1%</math>) is critical to the recommendations made. Furthermore, he says that a higher discount rate is consistence with market interest rates.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Nordhaus |first=William D. |date=September 2007 |title=A Review of the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change |url=https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/jel.45.3.686 |journal=Journal of Economic Literature |language=en |volume=45 |issue=3 |pages=686β702 |doi=10.1257/jel.45.3.686 |issn=0022-0515|url-access=subscription }}</ref> There is no consensus still on the climate discount rate that should be used. Considerations from experts span morality, interest rates, consumer preferences, intergenerational equity, and global equity. At the country level, the revealed environmental discount rates can span from 1%-10%.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Drupp |first1=Moritz A. |last2=Freeman |first2=Mark C. |last3=Groom |first3=Ben |last4=Nesje |first4=Frikk |date=2018 |title=Discounting Disentangled |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/26529055 |journal=American Economic Journal: Economic Policy |volume=10 |issue=4 |pages=109β134 |doi=10.1257/pol.20160240 |jstor=26529055 |issn=1945-7731|hdl=10852/70804 |hdl-access=free }}</ref>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)