Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Arrow–Debreu model
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== Number of equilibria === {{See also|General equilibrium theory#Uniqueness}} Certain economies at certain endowment vectors may have infinitely equilibrium price vectors. However, "generically", an economy has only finitely many equilibrium price vectors. Here, "generically" means "on all points, except a closed set of Lebesgue measure zero", as in [[Sard's theorem]].<ref>{{Citation |last=Debreu |first=Gérard |title=Stephen Smale and the Economic Theory of General Equilibrium |date=June 2000 |url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1142/9789812792815_0025 |work=The Collected Papers of Stephen Smale |pages=243–258 |publisher=World Scientific Publishing Company |doi=10.1142/9789812792815_0025 |isbn=978-981-02-4991-5 |access-date=2023-01-06}}</ref><ref>{{Citation |last=Smale |first=Steve |title=Chapter 8 Global analysis and economics |date=1981-01-01 |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1573438281010126 |series=Handbook of Mathematical Economics |volume=1 |pages=331–370 |publisher=Elsevier |doi=10.1016/S1573-4382(81)01012-6 |isbn=978-0-444-86126-9 |language=en |access-date=2023-01-06}}</ref> There are many such genericity theorems. One example is the following:<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Debreu |first=Gérard |date=December 1984 |title=Economic Theory in the Mathematical Mode |url=http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/3439651 |journal=The Scandinavian Journal of Economics |volume=86 |issue=4 |pages=393–410 |doi=10.2307/3439651 |jstor=3439651 |issn=0347-0520}}</ref><ref>(Starr 2011) Section 26.3</ref> {{Math theorem | name = Genericity | math_statement = For any strictly positive endowment distribution <math>r^1, ..., r^I \in \R_{++}^N</math>, and any strictly positive price vector <math>p\in \R_{++}^N</math>, define the excess demand <math>Z(p, r^1, ..., r^I)</math> as before. If on all <math>p, r^1, ..., r^I \in \R_{++}^N</math>, * <math>Z(p, r^1, ..., r^I)</math> is well-defined, * <math>Z</math> is differentiable, * <math>\nabla_p Z</math> has <math>(N-1)</math>, then for generically any endowment distribution <math>r^1, ..., r^I \in \R_{++}^N</math>, there are only finitely many equilibria <math>p^* \in \R_{++}^N</math>. }} {{Math proof|title=Proof (sketch)|proof= Define the "equilibrium manifold" as the set of solutions to <math>Z=0</math>. By Walras's law, one of the constraints is redundant. By assumptions that <math>\nabla_p Z</math> has rank <math>(N-1)</math>, no more constraints are redundant. Thus the equilibrium manifold has dimension <math>N \times I</math>, which is equal to the space of all distributions of strictly positive endowments <math>\R_{++}^{N \times I}</math>. By continuity of <math>Z</math>, the projection is closed. Thus by Sard's theorem, the projection from the equilibrium manifold to <math>\R_{++}^{N \times I}</math> is critical on only a set of measure 0. It remains to check that the preimage of the projection is generically not just discrete, but also finite. }}
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)