Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Anti-competitive practices
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
==Common anti-competitive actions== * [[Dumping (pricing policy)|Dumping]], also known as predatory pricing, is a commercial strategy for which a company sells a product at an aggressively low price in a competitive market at a loss. A company with large market share and the ability to temporarily sacrifice selling a product or service at below average cost can drive competitors out of the market,<ref>{{cite web |last1=Hemingway |first1=Carole |title=What is Predatory Pricing? |url=https://legalvision.com.au/what-is-predatory-pricing/ |website=LegalVision |access-date=18 October 2020 |archive-date=30 September 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20200930212823/https://legalvision.com.au/what-is-predatory-pricing/ |url-status=dead }}</ref> after which the company would be free to raise prices for a greater profit. For example, many developing countries have accused China of dumping. In 2006, the country was accused of dumping silk and satin in the Indian markets at a cheaper rate which affected the local manufacturers adversely.<ref>{{Cite news|url=http://news.bbc.co.uk/2/hi/business/5224370.stm|title=China faces Indian dumping allegations|last=Windle|first=Charlotte|date=July 31, 2006|publisher=[[BBC News]]|access-date=}}</ref> * [[Exclusive dealing]], where a retailer or wholesaler is obliged by contract to only purchase from the contracted supplier. This mechanism prevents retailers to lessen profit maximisation and/or [[consumer choice]].<ref>{{cite web |title=Exclusive Dealing |url=https://www.accc.gov.au/business/anti-competitive-behaviour/exclusive-dealing#:~:text=Broadly%20speaking%2C%20exclusive%20dealing%20occurs,when%20it%20substantially%20lessens%20competition |website=Australian Competition and Consumer Commission |date = 9 January 2013|publisher=ACCC |access-date=18 October 2020}}</ref> In 1999, Dentsply entered a 7 years court complaint by the U.S, the dental wholesaler had been successfully sued for using monopoly power to restrain trade using exclusive dealings within contract requirements.<ref>{{cite web |title=U.S. v. Dentsply International, Inc. |url=https://www.justice.gov/atr/case/us-v-dentsply-international-inc |website=The United States Department of Justice |date=25 June 2015 |access-date=19 October 2020}}</ref> * [[Price fixing]], where companies collude to set prices, effectively dismantling the free market by not engaging in competition with each other. In 2018, travel agency giant, Flight Centre was fined $12.5 million for encouraging a collusive price fixing plan between 3 international airlines from between 2005 and 2009.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Pash |first1=Chris |title=Flight Centre has been fined $12.5 million for 'price fixing' |url=https://www.businessinsider.com.au/flight-centre-fined-price-fixing-2018-4 |website=Business Insider Australia |date=4 April 2018 |access-date=18 October 2020 |archive-date=7 November 2020 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20201107021329/https://www.businessinsider.com.au/flight-centre-fined-price-fixing-2018-4 |url-status=dead }}</ref> * [[Refusal to deal]], e.g., two companies agree not to use a certain vendor. In 2010, Cabcharge refused, on commercial terms, to allow its non-cash payment instruments to be accepted and processed electronically by Travel Tab/Mpos' system for the payment of taxi fares. Travel Tab/Mpos requested access to the instruments but Cabcharge refused twice. Penalties for the first and second refusal were $2 million and $9 million respectively.<ref>{{cite web |title=ACCC v Cabcharge Australia Ltd |url=https://www.australiancompetitionlaw.org/cases/cabcharge2010.html |website=Australian Competition Law |publisher=AustFederal Court of Australiaralian Competition Law |access-date=22 October 2020}}</ref> * [[Dividing territories]], an agreement by two companies to stay out of each other's way and reduce competition in the agreed-upon territories. Also known as 'market sharing', a practice in which businesses geographically divide or allocate customers using contractual agreements that include non-competition on established customers, not producing the same goods or services and/or selling within specific regions.<ref>{{cite web |title=Market sharing |url=https://www.compcomm.hk/en/media/reports_publications/usefulresources_competition_2.html#:~:text=Market%20sharing%20is%20when%20competitors,and%20which%20customers%20to%20pursue. |publisher=Competition Commission (Hong Kong) |access-date=22 October 2020}}</ref> Boral and CSR formed a pre-mix concrete cartel and were penalized for bid rigging, price fixing and market sharing at an amount over $6.6million and a maximum of $100,000 on each of the 6 executives involved. The companies had agreed to recognize clients as belonging to suppliers without competition over regular meetings and phone conversations. Company market shares were monitored to ensure the agreement was not breached - this led to over-charging on construction quotes which were used by federal, state and local government projects.<ref>{{cite web |title=Cartels case studies & legal cases: Queensland pre-mixed concrete cartel |url=https://www.accc.gov.au/business/anti-competitive-behaviour/cartels/cartels-case-studies-legal-cases |website=Australian Competition and Consumer Commission |date=24 January 2013 |publisher=ACCC |access-date=23 October 2020}}</ref> * [[Tying (commerce)|Tying]], where products that are not naturally related must be purchased together. This incumbent strategy forces the buyer to purchase an unnecessary product from a separate market, implicitly lessening competition in various markets by increasing unnatural barriers to entry as entrants are unable to compete on a full line of products nor on price.<ref>{{cite web |last2=Khemani |first2=R. S |last1=Shapiro |first1=Daniel M |title=Glossary of industrial organisation economics and competition law |date=1993 |pages=83 |url=https://www.oecd.org/regreform/sectors/2376087.pdf}}</ref> In 2006, Apple iTunes iPod lost a $10 million 10 year antitrust case when iPods were sold between September 2006 to March 2009 that were only compatible with tracks from the iTunes Store or those downloaded from CDs.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Ware |first1=James |title=Apple iPod iTunes Antitrust Litigation |journal=United States District Court, N.D. California, San Jose Division |date=22 December 2008 |volume=C 05-00037 JW. |url=https://casetext.com/case/apple-ipod-itunes-antitrust-litigation |access-date=25 October 2020}}</ref> * [[Resale price maintenance]], when a manager sells to a distributor, the resale price is agreed to not fall below a specified minimum value. However, when the retail price decreases, the manufacturer does sell more products. This is interesting from a management perspective.<ref>{{Cite journal |first1=Roger |first2=Joseph |last1=Blair|last2=Whitman |date=2018 |title=Resale price maintenance: A managerial perspective |url=https://doi.org/10.1002/mde.2920 |journal=Managerial and Decision Economics|volume=39 |issue=7 |pages=751β760 |doi=10.1002/mde.2920 |s2cid=158821430|jstor= 26608277|url-access=subscription }}</ref> This strategy is controversial, and the benefits are to protect some inefficient small stores or manufacturers from competition threats. But at the same time, this strategy can easily lead to the level price cartel of brand operators. * Technology monopoly: This type of monopoly occurs when one company has exclusive control over a particular technology or innovation, thus enabling them to dominate the market. For example, a company that owns a patent for a breakthrough technology may have a technology monopoly. * Legal loopholes: This type of monopoly occurs when the government grants a company exclusive rights or privileges to operate in a particular market. For example, patents and Copyrights provide temporary monopolies to inventors and creators to encourage innovation and creativity. Unfair competition includes a number of areas of law involving acts by one competitor or group of competitors which harm another in the field, and which may give rise to [[Crime|criminal offenses]] and civil [[Cause of action|causes of action]]. The most common actions falling under the banner of unfair competition include: * Matters pertaining to [[antitrust]] law, known in the [[European Union]] as [[competition law]]. Antitrust violations constituting unfair competition occur when one competitor attempts to force others out of the market (or prevent others from entering the market) through tactics such as [[predatory pricing]] or obtaining exclusive purchase rights to raw materials needed to make a competing product. * [[Trademark infringement]] and [[passing off]], which occur when the maker of a product uses a name, logo, or other identifying characteristics to deceive consumers into thinking that they are buying the product of a competitor. In the [[United States]], this form of unfair competition is prohibited under the [[common law]] and by state statutes, and governed at the federal level by the [[Lanham Act]]. * [[Misappropriation]] of [[trade secret]]s, which occurs when one competitor uses [[espionage]], [[bribery]], or outright [[theft]] to obtain economically advantageous information in the possession of another. In the United States, this type of activity is forbidden by the [[Uniform Trade Secrets Act]] and the [[Economic Espionage Act of 1996]]. * [[Trade libel]], the spreading of false information about the quality or characteristics of a competitor's products, is prohibited at common law. * [[Tortious interference]], which occurs when one competitor convinces a party having a relationship with another competitor to breach a contract with, or duty to, the other competitor is also prohibited at common law. * Anti-competitive agreements: Firms may enter into agreements that limit competition, such as agreements to fix prices, limit production or supply, or divide markets. These agreements harm competition, reduce consumer choice and lead to higher prices or lower quality products or services. * Mergers and acquisitions that harm competition: Mergers and acquisitions that result in a significant reduction in market competition may be considered anti-competitive. This may include actions such as acquiring a competitor to eliminate or reduce competition, or merging to form a dominant market player who may engage in anti-competitive behavior. * Exclusive deals or tie-in arrangements: Companies may enter into exclusive deals or tie-in arrangements that require customers or suppliers to trade with them exclusively or purchase one product or service in order to obtain another. These practices can limit consumer choice and limit competition by preventing competitors from entering major distribution channels or markets. Also criticized are: * [[Takeover|Absorption of a competitor or competing technology]], where a powerful firm effectively co-opts or swallows its competitor rather than let it either compete directly or be absorbed by another firm * [[Subsidies]] from government which allow a firm to function without being profitable, giving them an advantage over competition or effectively barring competition * [[Regulations]] which place costly restrictions on firms that less wealthy firms cannot afford to implement * [[Protectionism]], [[tariffs]] and [[Import quota|quotas]] which give firms insulation from competitive forces * [[Patent misuse]] and [[copyright misuse]], such as fraudulently obtaining a [[patent]], [[copyright]], or other form of [[intellectual property]]; or using such legal devices to gain advantage in an unrelated market * [[Digital rights management]] which prevents owners from selling used media, as would normally be allowed by the [[first sale doctrine]]. * [[Occupational licensing]]<ref>[https://heinonline.org/HOL/LandingPage?handle=hein.journals/scid19&div=24&id=&page= Katsuyama, Neil. "The economics of occupational licensing: Applying antitrust economics to distinguish between beneficial and anticompetitive professional licenses." S. Cal. Interdisc. LJ 19 (2009): 565.]</ref><ref>[https://heinonline.org/HOL/LandingPage?handle=hein.journals/uclr44&div=8&id=&page= Gellhorn, Walter. "The abuse of occupational licensing." U. CHi. l. rev. 44 (1976): 6.]</ref> Various [[unfair business practices]] such as [[fraud]], [[misrepresentation]], and [[Unconscionability|unconscionable]] [[contract]]s may be considered unfair competition, if they give one competitor an advantage over others. In the [[European Union]], each member state must regulate unfair business practices in accordance with the principles laid down in the [[Unfair Commercial Practices Directive]], subject to transitional periods.
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)