Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Aggregate demand
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
===Aggregate demand-aggregate supply model=== {{Main|ADβAS model}} Sometimes, especially in textbooks, "aggregate demand" refers to an entire demand curve that ''looks'' like that in a typical [[Marshallian demand|Marshallian]] [[supply and demand]] diagram. [[File:AS + AD graph.svg|right|thumb|300px|Aggregate supply/demand graph]] Thus, we could refer to an "aggregate quantity demanded" (<math>Y^d = C + I_p + G + NX</math> in real or inflation-corrected terms) at any given aggregate average price level (such as the [[GDP deflator]]), <math>P</math>. In these diagrams, typically the <math>Y^d</math> rises as the average price level (<math>P</math>) falls, as with the <math>AD</math> line in the diagram. The main theoretical reason for this is that if the nominal [[money]] supply ('''M<sup>s</sup>''') is constant, a falling <math>P</math> implies that the [[Real vs. nominal in economics|real]] money supply (<math>\frac{M^s}{P}</math>)rises, encouraging lower [[interest rate]]s and higher spending. This is often called the "[[Keynes effect]]". Carefully using ideas from the [[theory]] of [[supply and demand]], [[aggregate supply]] can help determine the extent to which increases in aggregate demand lead to increases in real [[output (economics)|output]] or instead to increases in prices ([[inflation]]). In the diagram, an increase in any of the components of <math>AD</math> (at any given <math>P</math>) shifts the <math>AD</math> curve to the right. This increases both the level of real production (<math>Y</math>) and the average price level (<math>P</math>). But different levels of economic activity imply different mixtures of output and price increases. As shown, with very low levels of [[real vs. nominal in economics|real]] [[gross domestic product]] and thus large amounts of unemployed resources, most economists of the [[Keynesian economics|Keynesian school]] suggest that most of the change would be in the form of output and employment increases. As the economy gets close to [[potential output]] (<math>Y^*</math>), we would see more and more price increases rather than output increases as <math>AD</math> increases. Beyond <math>Y^*</math>, this gets more intense, so that price increases dominate. Worse, output levels greater than <math>Y^*</math> cannot be sustained for long. The <math>AS</math> is a ''short-term'' relationship here. If the economy persists in operating above potential, the <math>AS</math> curve will shift to the left, making the increases in real output transitory. At low levels of <math>Y</math>, the world is more complicated. First, most modern industrial economies experience few if any fall in prices. So the <math>AS</math> curve is unlikely to shift down or to the right. Second, when they do suffer price cuts (as in Japan), it can lead to disastrous [[deflation (economics)|deflation]].
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)