Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Underconsumption
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
=== 19th century === Malthus devoted a chapter of ''Principles'' (1836) to underconsumption theory, which was rebutted by [[David Ricardo]], in his ''Notes on Malthus,'' and which debate continued in private correspondence.<ref>Maclachlan, Fiona C. (Fiona Cameron), [http://muse.jhu.edu/login?uri=/journals/history_of_political_economy/v031/31.3maclachlan.html The Ricardo-Malthus Debate on Underconsumption: A Case Study in Economic Conversation] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20160304091539/http://muse.jhu.edu/login?uri=%2Fjournals%2Fhistory_of_political_economy%2Fv031%2F31.3maclachlan.html |date=2016-03-04 }}, History of Political Economy - Volume 31, Number 3, Fall 1999, pp. 563-574.</ref> Malthus was credited by Keynes as a predecessor for his views on [[effective demand]]<ref>Keynes, Essays in Biography, 1933, p. 103.</ref> and, other than Malthus, Keynes did not credit the existence of other proponents of underconsumption, stating instead that Ricardo "conquered" English economics.<ref>Keynes, General Theory, 1936, p. 32.</ref> This is now understood to be false – other British proponents of underconsumption are now well-established, but, as Keynes demonstrated, they were poorly documented, and by the 1930s not well-known. Further, they did not form a unified school, but rather related heterodox ideas.<ref>{{Cite journal| doi = 10.2307/2229348| journal = The Economic Journal| year = 1967| volume = 77| jstor = 2229348| issue = 305| title = Parson Malthus, the General and the Captain | first = R. D. C.| last1 = Black| pages = 59–74}}</ref> The [[Birmingham School (economics)|Birmingham School]] of economists argued an underconsumptionist theory from 1815,<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Checkland|first=S. G.|title=The Birmingham Economists, 1815-1850|journal=The Economic History Review|volume=1|issue=1|year=1948|publisher=Blackwell Publishing on behalf of the Economic History Society|jstor=2590000|pages=1–19|doi=10.2307/2590000}}</ref> and some of the writings of the school's leading member [[Thomas Attwood (economist)|Thomas Attwood]] contained formulations of the [[multiplier (economics)|multiplier]] effect and an [[income-expenditure model]].<ref>{{Cite book|last=Glasner|first=David|year=1997|contribution=Attwood, Thomas (1783-1856)|contribution-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=e1ZEPd_pQnoC&pg=PA22|editor-last=Glasner|editor-first=David|title=Business Cycles and Depressions: An Encyclopedia|publisher=Taylor & Francis|page=22|isbn=0-8240-0944-4|url=https://books.google.com/books?id=e1ZEPd_pQnoC|access-date=2009-06-15}}</ref> In continental Europe, [[Jean Charles Léonard de Sismondi]] proposed underconsumption and overproduction as causes of the [[economic cycle]], in his ''Nouveaux Principes d'économie politique'' (1819), in one of the earliest systematic treatments of economic cycles. Properly, Sismondi discussed periodic [[economic crisis|economic ''crises'']], while the notion of a ''cycle'' was devised by [[Charles Dunoyer]] in his reconciliation of Sismondi's work with classical economics. The [[multiplier (economics)|multiplier]] dates to work in the 1890s by the Australian economist Alfred De Lissa, the Danish politician [[Julius Wulff]], and the German-American economist [[Nicholas Johannsen]],<ref>[https://archive.org/details/originsofkeynes00dima/page/117 The origins of the Keynesian revolution], by Robert William Dimand, [https://archive.org/details/originsofkeynes00dima/page/117 p. 117]</ref><ref>Johannsen is cited in a footnote in: {{Cite book|title=[[A Treatise on Money]]|last=Keynes|first=John Maynard|date=1930|pages=90|author-link=John Maynard Keynes}}</ref> Nicholas Johannsen also proposed a theory of effective demand in the 1890s. The [[paradox of thrift]] was stated in 1892 by [[J. M. Robertson|John M. Robertson]] in his ''The Fallacy of Savings,'' and similar sentiments date to antiquity,<ref name="neglect">{{cite journal |title=A Neglected Early Statement the Paradox of Thrift |first1=Robert T. |last1=Nash |first2=William P. |last2=Gramm |journal=History of Political Economy |year=1969 |volume=1 |issue=2 |pages=395–400 |url=http://hope.dukejournals.org/cgi/pdf_extract/1/2/395 |doi=10.1215/00182702-1-2-395 |url-access=subscription }}</ref><ref>{{cite book |first=John M. |last=Robertson |author-link=J. M. Robertson |title=The Fallacy of Saving |year=1892 |url=https://archive.org/stream/fallacyofsavings00robe/fallacyofsavings00robe_djvu.txt }}</ref> in addition to the mercantilist statements cited above: {{Blockquote|There is that scattereth, and yet increaseth; and there is that withholdeth more than is meet, but it tendeth to poverty.<br/> The liberal soul shall be made fat: and he that watereth shall be watered also himself. |[[s:Bible (King James)/Proverbs#11:24|Proverbs 11:24–25]]}}
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)