Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Absolute advantage
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Economic concept}} {{Economics sidebar}} In [[economics]], the principle of '''absolute advantage''' is the ability of a party (an individual, or firm, or country) to produce a [[Goods and services|good or service]] more efficiently than its competitors.<ref>{{cite web |last1= |first1= |date=2023-06-08 |title=Absolute Advantage |url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/a/absoluteadvantage.asp |access-date=2023-06-27 |website=Investopedia}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|title=Absolute advantage {{!}} economics|url=https://www.britannica.com/topic/absolute-advantage|access-date=2020-10-21|website=Encyclopedia Britannica|language=en}}</ref> The Scottish economist [[Adam Smith]] first described the principle of absolute advantage in the context of [[international trade]] in 1776, using [[Labour economics|labor]] as the only input. Since absolute advantage is determined by a simple comparison of [[labor productivity|labor productiveness]], it is possible for a party to have no absolute advantage in anything.<ref name="encyclopedia 1" /> ==Origin of the theory== The concept of absolute advantage is generally attributed to the Scottish economist [[Adam Smith]] in his 1776 publication ''[[The Wealth of Nations]],'' in which he countered [[mercantilist]] ideas.<ref name="encyclopedia 1">{{cite encyclopedia|url=http://www.skidmore.edu/~mdas/AbsoluteandComparativeAdvantage.pdf|title=Absolute and Comparative Advantage |encyclopedia=International Encyclopedia of the Social Sciences|edition=2nd |pages=1–2|access-date=2009-05-04|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20100529042541/http://www.skidmore.edu/~mdas/AbsoluteandComparativeAdvantage.pdf|archive-date=2010-05-29|url-status=dead}}</ref><ref>{{Cite book|url=https://catalog.flatworldknowledge.com/bookhub/reader/28?e=fwk-61960-chab#fwk-61960-ch02_s02|title=International Trade: Theory and Policy|access-date=2018-09-18|archive-date=2019-01-01|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190101013503/https://catalog.flatworldknowledge.com/bookhub/reader/28?e=fwk-61960-chab#fwk-61960-ch02_s02|url-status=dead}}</ref> Smith argued that it was impossible for all nations to become rich simultaneously by following [[mercantilism]] because the export of one nation is another nation's import and instead stated that all nations would gain simultaneously if they practiced free trade and specialized in accordance with their absolute advantage.<ref name="encyclopedia 1" /> Smith also stated that the wealth of nations depends upon the goods and services available to their citizens, rather than their gold reserves.<ref name="washington">{{cite web|url=http://faculty.washington.edu/jwh/349lec03.htm|title=International Trade Theory |last=Harrington |first=James W. |work=Geography 349 Absolute advantage|publisher=University of Washington |access-date=2009-05-04}}</ref> Because Smith only focused on comparing labor productivities to determine absolute advantage, he did not develop the concept of [[comparative advantage]].<ref name="encyclopedia 1" /> While there are possible gains from trade with absolute advantage, the gains may not be mutually beneficial. Comparative advantage focuses on the range of possible mutually beneficial exchanges. ==Examples == ===Example 1=== {| class="wikitable floatright" style="text-align:center;" |+Figure 1 ! colspan="3" | '''Hours of work necessary to produce one unit''' |- ! scope="col" | Country ! scope="col" | Cloth ! scope="col" | Wine |- ! scope="row" | '''UK''' |80 |100 |- ! scope="row" | '''Portugal''' |120 |90 |} {| class="wikitable floatright" style="text-align:center;" |+Figure 2 ! colspan="3" | '''Hours of work to commit after the specialization''' |- ! scope="col" | Country ! scope="col" | Cloth ! scope="col" | Wine |- ! scope="row" | '''UK''' |80 + 100 |0 |- ! scope="row" | '''Portugal''' |0 |90 + 120 |} According to Figure 1, the UK commits 80 hours of labor to produce one unit of cloth, which is fewer than Portugal's hours of work necessary to produce one unit of cloth. The UK is able to produce one unit of cloth with fewer hours of labor, therefore the UK has an absolute advantage in the production of cloth. On the other hand, Portugal commits 90 hours to produce one unit of wine, which is fewer than the UK's hours of work necessary to produce one unit of wine. Therefore, Portugal has an absolute advantage in the production of wine. If the two countries specialize in producing the good for which they have the absolute advantage, and if they exchange part of the good with each other, both of the two countries can end up with more of each good than they would have in the absence of trade.<ref>{{citation | author = Bruce Bueno de Mesquita | publisher = Sage | title = Principles of International Politics |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=S7VG1yZP52gC&q=absolute+advantage+england+portugal&pg=PT357 | year = 2013 | pages = 329–330 | isbn = 9781483304663 }}</ref><ref name = "Daquila 2005">{{citation | author = Teofilo C. Daquila | publisher = Nova Publishers | title = The Economies of Southeast Asia: Indonesia, Malaysia, Philippines, Singapore, and Thailand |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=_aybCa4g1H4C&q=absolute+advantage | year = 2005 | page = 124 | isbn = 9781594541889 }}</ref> In the absence of trade, each country produces one unit of cloth and one unit of wine, i.e. a combined total production of 2 units of cloth and 2 units of wine. Here, if The UK commits all of its labor (80+100) for the production of cloth for which The UK has the absolute advantage, The UK produces (80+100)÷80=2.25 units of cloth. On the other hand, if Portugal commits all of its labor (90+120) for the production of wine, Portugal produces (90+120)÷90=2.33... units of wine. The combined total production in this case is 2.25 units of cloth and 2.33 units of wine which is greater than the total production of each good had there been no specialization. Assuming free trade this will lead to cheaper prices for both goods for both countries. ===Example 2=== You and your friends decided to help with fundraising for a local charity group by printing T-shirts and making birdhouses. *'''Scenario 1:''' One of your friends, Gina, can print 5 T-shirts or build 3 birdhouses an hour. Your other friend, Mike, can print 3 T-shirts an hour or build 2 birdhouses an hour. Because your friend Gina is more productive at printing T-shirts and building birdhouses compared to Mike, she has an absolute advantage in both printing T-shirts and building birdhouses. *'''Scenario 2:''' Suppose Gina wasn't as agile with the hammer and could only make 1 birdhouse an hour, but she took a [[screen printing]] class and could print 10 T-shirts an hour. Mike on the other hand takes woodworking and so he can build 5 birdhouses an hour, but he doesn't know the first thing about making T-shirts so he can only print 2 T-shirts an hour. While Gina would have the absolute advantage in printing shirts, Mike would have an absolute advantage in building birdhouses. ==Further reading== *{{cite book|last=Irwin |first=Douglas A.|year=1996|isbn=978-0691058962|title=Against the Tide: An Intellectual History of Free Trade|url=https://archive.org/details/againsttideintel00irwi |url-access=registration |publisher= Princeton University Press}} *{{cite book|last=Smith|first=Adam|year=1776|title=An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations (Vol 1)|isbn= 978-0865970069}} *{{cite book|last=Schumpeter|first=Joseph A.|year=1954|title=History of economic analysis|isbn=9781134838707|publisher=Routledge}} *{{cite journal|last=Trefler|first=Daniel|year=1995|title=The Case of the Missing Trade and Other Mysteries|journal=The American Economic Review|volume=85|issue=5|pages=1029–1046|jstor=2950973}} ==See also== {{Portal|Economics}} {{div col|colwidth=30em}} * [[Comparative advantage]] * [[Economies of scale]] * [[Gains from trade]] * [[Global labor arbitrage]] * [[Heckscher–Ohlin model]] * [[Intra-industry trade]] * [[New trade theory]] * ''[[On the Principles of Political Economy and Taxation]]'', by [[David Ricardo]] * [[Real wages]] * [[Relative price]] * [[Revealed comparative advantage]] * [[Ricardian model]] * [[Supply and demand]] * [[Trade]] {{div col end}} ==References== {{Reflist|2}} ==External links== {{wiktionary}} {{sister project links}} * [http://faculty.washington.edu/jwh/349lec03.htm#absolute Absolute Advantage], University of Washington {{Trade}} {{economics}} [[Category:International trade theory]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite encyclopedia
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Div col
(
edit
)
Template:Div col end
(
edit
)
Template:Economics
(
edit
)
Template:Economics sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Portal
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:Sister project
(
edit
)
Template:Sister project links
(
edit
)
Template:Trade
(
edit
)
Template:Wiktionary
(
edit
)