Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Cross elasticity of demand
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Economic measure of a good's price change}} {{Economics sidebar}} In [[economics]], the '''cross''' (or '''cross-price''') '''elasticity of demand''' ('''XED''') measures the effect of changes in the price of one [[Good (economics)|good]] on the [[Demand|quantity demanded]] of another good. This reflects the fact that the quantity demanded of good is dependent on not only its own price ([[price elasticity of demand]]) but also the price of other "related" good. The cross elasticity of demand is calculated as the [[ratio]] between the percentage change of the quantity demanded for a good and the percentage change in the [[price]] of another good, [[ceteris paribus]]:<ref>{{Cite web|title=OECD Glossary of Statistical Terms β Cross price elasticity of demand Definition|url=https://stats.oecd.org/glossary/detail.asp?ID=3185|access-date=2021-04-17|website=stats.oecd.org}}</ref><math display="block">\text{XED} = \frac{\%\text{ change in quantity demanded of good A}}{\%\text{ change in price of good B}}</math>The [[Sign (mathematics)|sign]] of the cross elasticity indicates the relationship between two goods. A negative cross elasticity denotes two products that are '''complements''', while a positive cross elasticity denotes two products are '''substitutes'''. If products A and B are complements, an increase in the price of B leads to a decrease in the quantity demanded for A, as A is used in conjunction with B.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Hemmati|first1=M.|last2=Fatemi Ghomi|first2=S.M.T.|last3=Sajadieh|first3=Mohsen S.|date=2017-09-04|title=Inventory of complementary products with stock dependent demand under vendor managed inventory with consignment policy|journal=Scientia Iranica|pages=0|doi=10.24200/sci.2017.4457|issn=2345-3605|doi-access=free}}</ref> Equivalently, if the price of product B decreases, the demand curve for product A shifts to the right reflecting an increase in A's demand, resulting in a ''negative'' value for the cross elasticity of demand. If A and B are substitutes, an increase in the price of B will increase the market demand for A, as customers would easily replace B with A,<ref>{{Citation|last1=Das|first1=R. L.|title=Some Studies on EPQ Model of Substitutable Products Under Imprecise Environment|date=2019-09-01|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1007/978-981-13-9698-4_18|work=Asset Analytics|pages=331β360|place=Singapore|publisher=Springer Singapore|isbn=978-981-13-9697-7|access-date=2021-04-17|last2=Jana|first2=R. K.|doi=10.1007/978-981-13-9698-4_18|s2cid=202935211|url-access=subscription}}</ref> like McDonald's and Domino's Pizza. == History == [[File:Alfred Marshall - Principles of Economics (1890), Prometheus Books.JPG|thumb|Alfred Marshall's book, where the concept 'price elasticity of demand' originated from]] The concept of "price elasticity of demand" originated by [[Alfred Marshall]] predicted relative changes between price and quantity. In the [[Cellophane paradox|Cellophane case]], Professor Stocking believed that a change in the price of one product will induce a price change of its ''rivalry'' in the same direction, so he firstly regarded that movement of two prices in the same direction explicitly reflects a high cross-price elasticity.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Lishan|first=John M.|date=1959|title=The Cellophane Case and the Cross-Elasticity of Demand|url=https://heinonline.org/HOL/Page?handle=hein.journals/antibull4&id=593&div=&collection=|journal=Antitrust Bulletin|volume=4|pages=593}}</ref> However, during 1924β1940, du Pont cellophane prices moved independently from its perceived competitors' (waxed paper, vegetable parchment, etc) price; independent price movements reflect noncompetitive pricing between cellophane and its rival products.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Waldman |first1=Don |title=The du Pont Cellophane Case Revisited: An Analysis of the Indirect Effects of Antitrust Policy on Market Structure and Performance |volume=25 |issue=4 |page=805 |journal=Antitrust Bulletin |date=1980 |doi=10.1177/0003603X8002500406 |s2cid=240425105 |access-date=25 April 2021 |url=https://heinonline.org/HOL/P?h=hein.journals/antibull25&i=839|url-access=subscription }}</ref> Thus, Professor Stocking's emphasis on the same movement of prices was too rigid, as the price of cellophane changed induced by three factors: #Change in demand due to price change of rival products #The production function of the cellophane #The slope and position of the cost curves of rival products. In other words, the competitive relationship between two goods (cross-price elasticity) can not be simply concluded by price change, as price change arises from both [[cost]] and [[demand]] factors. Furthermore, instead of a high positive or low positive elasticity concluded by observing respective price change, cross-elasticity of demand should be either '''positive or negative''' to represent if there is a '''complementary or substitutive relationship''' between two goods. == Calculation and interpretation == Cross elasticity of demand of '''product B with respect to product A (''Ξ·''<sub>BA</sub>)''': : <math>\eta_{BA}=\frac{\Delta Q_B/Q_B}{\Delta P_A/P_A} = \frac{P_A}{Q_B} \cdot \frac{\Delta Q_B}{\Delta P_A}</math> <math>\eta_{BA}>0</math> implies two goods are '''substitutes'''. Consumers purchase more B when the price of A increases. Example: the cross elasticity of demand of butter with respect to margarine is 0.81, so 1% increase in the price of margarine will increase the demand for butter by 0.81%. <math>\eta_{BA}<0</math> implies two goods are '''complements'''. Consumers purchase less B when the price of A increases. Example: the cross elasticity of demand of entertainment with respect to food is β0.72, so 1% increase in the price of food will decrease the demand for entertainment by 0.72%. <math>\eta_{BA}=0</math> implies two goods are '''independent''' (a price change of good A is '''unrelated''' to demand change of good B), so changes in the price of product A have no effect on the demand for Product B. Example: bread and cloths . {| class="wikitable" |+Interpretation of cross elasticity of demand<ref>{{Cite web|title=Lesson Overview β Cross Price Elasticity and Income Elasticity of Demand (article)|url=https://www.khanacademy.org/economics-finance-domain/microeconomics/elasticity-tutorial/income-elasticity-of-demand/a/lesson-overview-cross-price-elasticity-and-income-elasticity-of-demand|access-date=2021-04-18|website=Khan Academy|language=en}}</ref> !If the sign of cross elasticity of demand is... !the elasticity range !the goods are |- |negative |ββ |perfect complements |- |negative |{{open-open|ββοΌ0}} |highly or somewhat complements |- |0 |0 |unrelated goods (neither complements or substitutes) |- |positive |{{open-open|0, +β}} |somewhat or highly substitutes |- |positive | +β |perfect substitutes |} === Degree of response === The '''higher''' the positive cross elasticity of demand, the '''more substitutable''' two products are; thus, the more competition between them. Similarly, the '''lower''' the negative cross elasticity of demand, the '''more complementary''' two goods are. In general, monopolies usually possess a low-positive cross elasticity of demand with respect to their competitors.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Clark |first1=J. M. |title=Review of Value and Capital: An Inquiry into Some Fundamental Principles of Economic Theory. |journal=Political Science Quarterly |date=1940 |volume=55 |issue=1 |pages=127β129 |doi=10.2307/2143778 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/2143778 |access-date=7 June 2024 |issn=0032-3195|url-access=subscription }}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |last1=SurΓ‘nyi-Unger |first1=Theo |title=The Concept of Elasticity in Economics |journal=Weltwirtschaftliches Archiv |date=1949 |volume=62 |pages=11β27 |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/40432297 |access-date=7 June 2024 |issn=0043-2636}}</ref><ref>{{cite journal |title= G. J. Stigler ''The Theory of Price''. New York, Macmillan, 1952, VII p. 340 P|journal= Bulletin de l'Institut de Recherches Γconomiques et Sociales|date=1953 |volume=19 |issue=1 |pages=97 |doi=10.1017/S1373971900100782}}</ref> ==== Elastic demand ==== If the absolute value of the cross elasticity of demand is greater than 1, the cross elasticity of demand is '''elastic''', this means that a change in price of good A results in a '''more than proportionate''' change in quantity demanded for good B. In other words, a change in price of good A has a ''relatively'' high impact on the change in quantity demanded for good B. <math display="block">|XED|>1</math> ==== Inelastic demand ==== If the absolute value of the cross elasticity of demand between 1 and 0, the cross elasticity of demand is '''inelastic''', this means that a change in price of good A results in a '''less than proportionate''' change in quantity demanded for good B. In other words, a change in price of good A has a ''relatively'' small impact on the change in quantity demanded for good B. <math display="block">0<|XED|<1</math> ==== Unitary demand ==== If the value of the cross elasticity of demand is 1, the cross elasticity of demand is '''unitary''', this means that a change in price of good A results in an exactly '''proportionate''' change in quantity demanded for good B. <math display="block">XED=1</math> ==Results for main types of goods== For two goods, fuel and new cars (consists of fuel consumption), are ''[[complement good|complements]]''; that is, one is used with the other. In these cases the cross elasticity of demand will be ''negative'', as shown by the decrease in demand for cars when the price for fuel will rise. In the case of perfect substitutes, the cross elasticity of demand is equal to positive infinity (at the point when both goods can be consumed). Where the two goods are ''[[Independent goods|independent]]'', or, as described in [[consumer theory]], if a good is independent in demand then the demand of that good is independent of the quantity consumed of all other goods available to the consumer, the cross elasticity of demand will be ''zero'' i.e. if the price of one good changes, there will be no change in demand for the other good. {| |[[Image:Cross elasticity of demand complements.svg|thumb|upright|200px|Two goods that complement each other show a negative cross elasticity of demand: as the price of good Y rises, the demand for good X falls]] |[[Image:Cross elasticity of demand substitutes.svg|thumb|upright|200px|Two goods that are substitutes have a positive cross elasticity of demand: as the price of good Y rises, the demand for good X rises]] |[[Image:Cross elasticity of demand independent.svg|thumb|upright|200px|Two goods that are independent have a zero cross elasticity of demand: as the price of good Y rises, the demand for good X stays constant]] |} When goods are substitutable, the diversion ratio, which quantifies how much of the displaced demand for product ''j'' switches to product ''i'', is measured by the ratio of the cross-elasticity to the own-elasticity multiplied by the ratio of product ''i''{{'}}s demand to product ''j''{{'}}s demand. In the discrete case, the diversion ratio is naturally interpreted as the fraction of product ''j'' demand which treats product ''i'' as a second choice,<ref>{{Cite journal|jstor = 1391869|title = Relating Elasticities to Changes in Demand|last1 = Bordley|first1 = Robert F.|journal = Journal of Business & Economic Statistics|year = 1985|volume = 3|issue = 2|pages = 156β158| doi=10.2307/1391869 }}</ref><ref>Capps, O. and Dharmasena, S., "Enhancing the Teaching of Product Substitutes/Complements: A Pedagogical Note on Diversion Ratios",''Applied Economics Teaching Resources'', Vol. 1, Issue 1, pp. 32β45, (2019), https://www.aaea.org/UserFiles/file/AETR_2019_001ProofFinal_v1.pdf</ref> measuring how much of the demand diverting from product ''j'' because of a price increase is diverted to product ''i'' can be written as the product of the ratio of the cross-elasticity to the own-elasticity and the ratio of the demand for product ''i'' to the demand for product ''j''. In some cases, it has a natural interpretation as the proportion of people buying product ''j'' who would consider product ''i'' their "second choice". Approximate estimates of the cross price elasticities of preference-independent bundles of goods (e.g. food and education, healthcare and clothing, etc.) can be calculated from the income elasticities of demand and market shares of individual bundles, using established models of demand based on a differential approach.<ref>{{Cite journal|doi=10.1371/journal.pone.0151390|title=Relationship between the Uncompensated Price Elasticity and the Income Elasticity of Demand under Conditions of Additive Preferences|year=2016|last1=Sabatelli|first1=Lorenzo|journal=PLOS ONE|volume=11|issue=3|pages=e0151390|pmid=26999511|pmc=4801373|arxiv=1602.08644|bibcode=2016PLoSO..1151390S|doi-access=free}}</ref> ===Selected cross price elasticities of demand=== Below are some examples of the cross-price elasticity of demand (XED) for various goods:<ref>Frank (2008) p. 186.</ref> {| class="wikitable" |- ! Good !! Good with price change !! XED |- | Butter || Margarine || +0.81 |- | Beef || Pork || +0.28 |- | Entertainment || Food || β0.72 |} == Application and Implication == An enterprise needs to understand the cross-elastic demand for a product or service. Cross-elastic demand can help enterprises set prices and identify the sensitivity of others to their products. For example, a strategic "loss leader" takes advantage of the negative cross elasticity of demand for complementary commodities to price in a counterintuitive way deliberately. A company can sell one of its goods for less than the cost of making it and thus promote sales of its complementary products. Large profits on complementary products can make up for net losses in the business of its main products. Many large companies use this strategy, such as Sony. Sony's PlayStation consoles are sold below the cost of making them, encouraging the sale of games. Games and consoles are almost perfectly complementary. The reduction in the price of consoles will significantly increase the demand for games. As a result, Sony can make up for its net losses in the console business by making big profits in games <ref>{{Cite journal|last=LIU|first=HONGJU|date=2010|title=Dynamics of Pricing in the Video Game Console Market: Skimming or Penetratio |journal=Journal of Marketing Research|volume=47|issue=3|pages=428β43|doi=10.1509/jmkr.47.3.428|jstor=25674441|s2cid=153931398}}</ref> Besides, unique and irreplaceable products enable companies to sell their products at higher prices. Because of the uniqueness of the product, companies do not worry too much about consumers switching to other products. However, the specific price setting should also follow the demand curve of the commodity. Suppose the elasticity of demand for the product is greater than 1. In that case, it means that a slight change in the product's price will cause a significant reduction in the consumer demand for the product. Therefore, companies should first make a careful study of the elasticity of demand for their products before setting prices. It ensures a broader profit range for the company. A real-life example is Apple. Apple used iOS, which is different from Android, at the beginning of the launch of their phones. The clean and straightforward interface is an irreplaceable advantage of this system. Apple, meanwhile, has its unique text-message tone and call ringtone. In many small ways, Apple is building uniqueness. Phone users who are used to iOS develop a habit that makes it difficult to adapt to other systems, such as Android. Finally, the providers of substitutes need to be aware of the competitors of their products through detailed market research. The company can reduce the sensitivity of competitors' products by increasing customer loyalty. For example, the recently hot quality stars are invited to endorse their company's products. It can attract some of the star's loyalists to the product, thus increasing the overall loyalty. Alternatively, the company could spend more money on advertising to make consumers aware of the difference between its product and that of its competitors. === Contribution to policy improvement=== The UK and Scottish governments intended to use price-based policy interventions, like setting minimum unit pricing and increasing taxation to reduce alcohol consumption and mediate the related harms among their population.<ref>{{cite journal |title=Estimation of own and cross price elasticities of alcohol demand in the UKβA pseudo-panel approach using the Living Costs and Food Survey 2001β2009 |journal=Journal of Health Economics |date=1 March 2014 |volume=34 |pages=96β103 |doi=10.1016/j.jhealeco.2013.12.006|last1=Meng |first1=Yang |last2=Brennan |first2=Alan |last3=Purshouse |first3=Robin |last4=Hill-Mcmanus |first4=Daniel |last5=Angus |first5=Colin |last6=Holmes |first6=John |last7=Meier |first7=Petra Sylvia |issue=100 |pmid=24508846 |pmc=3991422 }}</ref> Estimation of cross-price elasticities of alcohol in respect to other related beverages helps set price-based policy interventions, as it measures the percentage change in demand for one type of alcohol due to a 1% change in the price of another type of beverage. For example, the cross elasticity of demand for wine in respect to the price change of spirit is 0.05, which implies that a 1% price decrease for Spirit will reduce market demand for wine by 0.05%. Therefore, the cross elasticity of demand enables policymakers to take better control of the policy effects, thus, reducing the risk for mortality, morbidity, and other social harms caused by over-drinking. ===Contribution to the sustainable supply chain=== A high coefficient of negative cross-price elasticity implies that the sales of product A are decided by the sales of product B. If the demand of A significantly depends on the demand of B, there must be a reduction in the profit of A. In this case, the cross elasticity of demand is a reminder to the firms to cautiously selecting products with high dependence on complements. On the other hand, the high-positive cross elasticity of demand reflects high substitutability of goods, which means customers' demand can be fulfilled by other products easily. Businesses that understand the implications of high-positive cross elasticity of demand can reduce their operating risk by avoiding overstock, thus, maintaining a sustainable supply chain. ===Contribution to firm reactions=== Knowledge of a firm's cross elasticity of demand and their competitors' allows them to map out the market, enabling them to calculate the number of rivals and the importance of their complementary (and substitute) products relative to their own. Firms can develop strategies to reduce their exposure to the risks they are imposed to by price changes of other firms, such as an increase in the price of a complement or a decrease in the price of a substitute.<ref>{{cite web |title=Cross elasticity of demand |url=https://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Competitive_markets/Cross_elasticity_of_demand.html |website=Economics Online |access-date=26 April 2021 |date=13 January 2020}}</ref> === Potential strategies === ==== Horizontal integration ==== In markets with few competitors, cross elasticity between rivals are likely to be high,<ref>{{cite web |title=Cross elasticity of demand {{!}} Economics Online {{!}} Economics Online |url=https://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Competitive_markets/Cross_elasticity_of_demand.html |website=Economics Online |access-date=26 April 2021 |date=13 January 2020}}</ref> this makes firms in the market vulnerable to [[price competition]]. Horizontal integration, usually [[mergers]], could reduce said risks by reducing competition in the market. For example, when [[Anheuser-Busch InBev]] (the world's biggest brewer at the time) acquired [[SABMiller]] (InBev's closest rival) in 2015, it was one of the biggest takeover of a British firm, creating the world's first global brewer.<ref>{{cite news |title=SABMiller agrees AB Inbev takeover deal of Β£68bn |url=https://www.theguardian.com/business/2015/oct/13/sabmiller-agrees-ab-inbev-takeover-68bn |access-date=26 April 2021 |work=the Guardian |date=13 October 2015 |language=en}}</ref> The takeover created a brewing empire that produces a third of the world's beer. ==== Vertical integration ==== Firms may gain better control of the market by merging with suppliers of complementary products. Developing their own complementary products is another possible solution. For example, Google developing [[Google Pixel]] is an attempt by Google to capture the smartphone market share by integrating both its software and hardware features for improved performance while being more resource efficient.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Inc |first1=Spiceworks |title=Snapback: Google Pixel and the move towards vertical integration |url=https://community.spiceworks.com/topic/1860664-snapback-google-pixel-and-the-move-towards-vertical-integration |website=The Spiceworks Community |access-date=26 April 2021 |language=en}}</ref> [[File:Google Pixel and Pixel XL smartphones (30155267665).jpg|thumb|Google Pixel and Pixel XL smartphones]] ==== Alliances and collusion ==== Competitors may pool resources to create a joint alliance, such as [[Sony-Ericsson]] in October of 2001. [[Sony Electronics|Sony]] had a share of less than 1% in the mobile phone market; while Ericsson was the third largest market share holder. Unfortunately, [[Ericsson]] relied heavily on a single supplier, and when a fire broke out at a [[Royal Philips Electronics|Phillips]] factory, Ericsson couldn't fulfill their orders. Sony wanted a greater market share and Ericsson wanted to avoid going out of business, hence the Sony-Ericsson joint venture was formed.<ref>{{cite web |title=History of sony ericsson as a company |url=https://www.auessays.com/essays/business/history-of-sony-ericsson.php |website=AUEssays.com |access-date=26 April 2021 |language=en}}</ref> Firms entering into a price fixing agreement in order to avoid [[price wars]] means they are involved in a [[collusion]]. The chances of collusion to occur is higher in markets with few competitors such as [[Oligopolistic|oligopolistic markets]]. It is illegal according to [[antitrust laws]], even though collusive agreements may be implicit, its implication with cartels are the same. ==See also== * [[Economics]] * [[Supply and demand]] * [[Elasticity (economics)]] * [[Price elasticity of demand]] * [[Price elasticity of supply]] * [[Income elasticity of demand]] * [[Arc elasticity]] * [[Yield elasticity of bond value]] ==Notes== {{reflist}} ==References== * {{Cite book|last=Frank|first=Robert|year=2008|title=Microeconomics and Behavior|edition=7th|publisher=McGraw-Hill|isbn=978-0-07-126349-8}} * {{Cite book|last=Mankiw|first=Gregory|year=2009|title=Principles of Microeconomics|edition=5|publisher=South-Western College Pub|isbn=9780324589979}} ==External links== * [http://www.fapri.iastate.edu/tools/elasticity.aspx Database for Commodity Elasticity] at [https://www.econ.iastate.edu/fapri-food-and-agricultural-policy-research-institute Food and Agricultural Policy Research Institute], [[University of Iowa]] * {{cite web |title=Other Demand Elasticities |url=https://courses.lumenlearning.com/boundless-economics/chapter/other-demand-elasticities/#:~:text=For%20independent%20goods%2C%20the%20cross,for%20good%20X%20stays%20constant. |website=Lumen Learning |access-date=26 April 2021}} * {{cite web |title=Cross Elasticity of Demand |url=https://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Competitive_markets/Cross_elasticity_of_demand.html |website=Economics Online |date=13 January 2020 |access-date=26 April 2021}} {{Microeconomics}} {{Population}} [[Category:Elasticity (economics)]] [[Category:Demand]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:'
(
edit
)
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite news
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Economics sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Icon
(
edit
)
Template:Longitem
(
edit
)
Template:Microeconomics
(
edit
)
Template:Navbox
(
edit
)
Template:Nowrap
(
edit
)
Template:Open-open
(
edit
)
Template:Population
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)