Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Economic surplus
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Concept in economics}} {{About|consumers' and producers' surplus|information about other surpluses|Surplus (disambiguation){{!}}Surplus}} [[File:Economic-surpluses.svg|thumb|275px|Graph illustrating consumer (red) and producer (blue) surpluses on a supply and demand chart]] {{Capitalism sidebar}} In [[mainstream economics]], '''economic surplus''', also known as '''total welfare''' or '''total social welfare''' or '''Marshallian surplus''' (after [[Alfred Marshall]]), is either of two related quantities: * '''Consumer surplus''', or '''consumers' surplus''', is the monetary gain obtained by [[consumer]]s because they are able to purchase a product for a [[price]] that is less than the highest price that they would be [[Willingness to pay|willing to pay]]. * '''Producer surplus''', or '''producers' surplus''', is the amount that producers benefit by selling at a [[Market value|market price]] that is higher than the least that they would be [[Willingness to accept|willing to sell for]]; this is roughly equal to [[profit (accounting)|profit]] (since producers are not normally willing to sell at a loss and are normally indifferent to selling at a [[Break-even (economics)|break-even]] price).<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Boulding|first=Kenneth E.|date=1945|title=The Concept of Economic Surplus|jstor=1812599|journal=The American Economic Review|volume=35|issue=5|pages=851β869}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.khanacademy.org/economics-finance-domain/microeconomics/consumer-producer-surplus|title=Consumer and producer surplus{{!}}Microeconomics{{!}}Khan Academy|website=Khan Academy|language=en}}</ref> The sum of consumer and producer surplus is sometimes known as '''social surplus''' or '''total surplus'''; a decrease in that total from inefficiencies is called [[deadweight loss]].<ref>{{Cite web |title=Economic efficiency (article) |url=https://www.khanacademy.org/economics-finance-domain/microeconomics/consumer-producer-surplus/deadweight-loss-tutorial/a/demand-supply-and-efficiency-cnx |access-date=2023-07-15 |website=Khan Academy |language=en}}</ref> == Overview == In the mid-19th century, engineer [[Jules Dupuit]] first propounded the concept of economic surplus, but it was the economist [[Alfred Marshall]] who gave the concept its fame in the field of [[economics]]. On a standard [[supply and demand]] diagram, consumer surplus is the area (triangular if the supply and demand curves are linear) above the equilibrium price of the good and below the demand curve. This reflects the fact that consumers would have been willing to buy a single unit of the good at a price higher than the equilibrium price, a second unit at a price below that but still above the equilibrium price, etc., yet they in fact pay just the equilibrium price for each unit they buy. Likewise, in the supply-demand diagram, producer surplus is the area below the equilibrium price but above the supply curve. This reflects the fact that producers would have been willing to supply the first unit at a price lower than the equilibrium price, the second unit at a price above that but still below the [[equilibrium price]], etc., yet they in fact receive the equilibrium price for all the units they sell. ==History== Early writers of economic issues used surplus as a means to draw conclusions about the relationship between production and necessities. In the agricultural sector surplus was an important concept because this sector has the responsibility to feed everyone plus itself. Food is notable because people only need a specific amount of food and can only consume a limited amount. This means that excess food production must overflow to other people, and will not be rationally hoarded. The non-agricultural sector is therefore limited by the agricultural sector equaling the output of food subtracting the amount consumed by the agricultural sector. [[William Petty]]<ref name=":0"> Brewer A. (2008) Surplus. In: Palgrave Macmillan (eds) The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Palgrave Macmillan, London. https://doi.org/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_2208-1</ref> used a broad definition of necessities, leading him to focus on employment issues surrounding surplus. Petty explains a hypothetical example in which there is a territory of 1000 men and 100 of those men are capable of producing enough food for all 1000 men. The question becomes, what will the rest of the men do if only 100 are needed to provide necessities? He thereby suggests a variety of employments with some remaining unemployed.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Petty|first=William|date=1899-11-11|title=The Economic Writings of Sir William Petty|url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1093/nq/s9-iv.98.409b|journal=Cambridge: Cambridge University Press|volume=2|issue=98|page=30|doi=10.1093/nq/s9-iv.98.409b|issn=1471-6941|hdl=2027/hvd.li4qq6|hdl-access=free}}</ref> [[David Hume]] approached the agricultural surplus concept from another direction. Hume recognized that agriculture may feed more than those who cultivate it, but questioned why farmers would work to produce more than they need. Forceful production, which may occur under a feudal system, would be unlikely to generate a notable surplus in his opinion. Yet, if they could purchase luxuries and other goods beyond their necessities, they would become incentivized to produce and sell a surplus. Hume did not see this concept as abstract theory, he stated it as a fact when discussing how England developed after the introduction of foreign luxuries in his [[The History of England (Hume)|History of England]].<ref name=":0" /> [[Adam Smith]]'s thoughts on surplus drew on Hume. Smith noted that the desire for luxuries is infinite compared to the finite capacity of hunger. Smith saw the development in Europe as originating from landlords placing more importance on luxury spending rather than political power.<ref name=":0" /> ==Consumer surplus== Consumer surplus is the difference between the maximum price a consumer is willing to pay and the actual price they do pay. If a consumer is willing to pay more for a unit of a good than the current asking price, they are getting more benefit from the purchased product than they would if the price was their maximum willingness to pay. They are receiving the same benefit, the obtainment of the good, at a lesser cost.<ref name="Slesnick 2008">{{Cite encyclopedia | doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_626-2|chapter=Consumer Surplus|encyclopedia=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics| pages=1β7| year=2008| last1=Slesnick| first1=Daniel T.| isbn=978-1-349-95121-5}}</ref> An example of a good with generally high consumer surplus is drinking water. People would pay very high prices for drinking water, as they need it to survive. The difference in the price that they would pay, if they had to, and the amount that they pay now is their consumer surplus. The utility of the first few liters of drinking water is very high (as it prevents death), so the first few liters would likely have more consumer surplus than subsequent quantities. The maximum amount a consumer would be willing to pay for a given quantity of a good is the sum of the maximum price they would pay for the first unit, the (lower) maximum price they would be willing to pay for the second unit, etc. Typically these prices are decreasing; they are given by the individual [[demand curve]], which must be generated by a rational consumer who maximizes utility subject to a budget constraint.<ref name="Slesnick 2008"/> Because the demand curve is downward sloping, there is diminishing [[marginal utility]]. Diminishing marginal utility means a person receives less additional utility from an additional unit. However, the price of a product is constant for every unit at the equilibrium price. The extra money someone would be willing to pay for the number units of a product less than the equilibrium quantity and at a higher price than the equilibrium price for each of these quantities is the benefit they receive from purchasing these quantities.<ref>{{Cite web | url=https://www.investopedia.com/terms/c/consumer_surplus.asp | title=What a Consumer Surplus Tells Us}}</ref> For a given price the consumer buys the amount for which the consumer surplus is highest. The consumer's surplus is highest at the largest number of units for which, even for the last unit, the maximum willingness to pay is not below the [[market price]]. Consumer surplus can be used as a measurement of social welfare, shown by Robert Willig.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Willig|first=Robert D.|date=1976|title=Consumer's Surplus Without Apology|url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1806699|journal=The American Economic Review|volume=66|issue=4|pages=589β597|jstor=1806699 |issn=0002-8282}}</ref> For a single price change, consumer surplus can provide an approximation of changes in welfare. With multiple price and/or income changes, however, consumer surplus cannot be used to approximate economic welfare because it is not single-valued anymore. More modern methods are developed later to estimate the welfare effect of price changes using consumer surplus. The aggregate consumers' surplus is the sum of the consumer's surplus for all individual consumers. This aggregation can be represented graphically, as shown in the above graph of the market demand and supply curves. The aggregate consumers' surplus can also be said to be the maxim of satisfaction a consumer derives from particular goods and services. ===Calculation from supply and demand=== The consumer surplus (individual or aggregated) is the area under the (individual or aggregated) demand curve and above a horizontal line at the actual price (in the aggregated case, the equilibrium price). If the demand curve is a straight line, the consumer surplus is the area of a triangle: :<math>CS = \frac{1}{2} Q_{\mathrm{mkt}} \left( P_{\max} - P_{\mathrm{mkt}} \right),</math> where ''P''<sub>mkt</sub> is the equilibrium price (where supply equals demand), ''Q''<sub>mkt</sub> is the total quantity purchased at the equilibrium price, and ''P''<sub>max</sub> is the price at which the quantity purchased would fall to 0 (that is, where the demand curve intercepts the price axis). For more general demand and supply functions, these areas are not triangles but can still be found using [[integral]] calculus. Consumer surplus is thus the definite integral of the demand function with respect to price, from the market price to the maximum reservation price (i.e., the price-intercept of the demand function): :<math>CS = \int^{P_{\max}}_{P_{\mathrm{mkt}}} D(P)\, dP, </math> where <math>D(P_{\max}) = 0. </math> This shows that if we see a rise in the equilibrium price and a fall in the equilibrium quantity, then consumer surplus falls. ===Calculation of a change in consumer surplus=== The change in consumer surplus is used to measure the changes in prices and income. The demand function used to represent an individual's demand for a certain product is essential in determining the effects of a price change. An individual's demand function is a function of the individual's income, the demographic characteristics of the individual, and the vector of commodity prices. When the price of a product changes, the change in consumer surplus is measured as the negative value of the integral from the original actual price (''P''<sub>0</sub>) and the new actual price (''P''<sub>1</sub>) of the demand for product by the individual. If the change in consumer surplus is positive, the price change is said to have increased the individuals welfare. If the price change in consumer surplus is negative, the price change is said to have decreased the individual's welfare.<ref name="Slesnick 2008"/> === Distribution of benefits when price falls === When supply of a good expands, the price falls (assuming the demand curve is downward sloping) and consumer surplus increases. This benefits two groups of people: consumers who were already willing to buy at the initial price benefit from a price reduction, and they may buy more and receive even more consumer surplus; and additional consumers who were unwilling to buy at the initial price will buy at the new price and also receive some consumer surplus. Consider an example of linear supply and demand curves. For an initial supply curve ''S''<sub>0</sub>, consumer surplus is the triangle above the line formed by price ''P''<sub>0</sub> to the demand line (bounded on the left by the price axis and on the top by the demand line). If supply expands from ''S''<sub>0</sub> to ''S''<sub>1</sub>, the consumers' surplus expands to the triangle above P<sub>1</sub> and below the demand line (still bounded by the price axis). The change in consumer's surplus is difference in area between the two triangles, and that is the consumer welfare associated with expansion of supply. Some people were willing to pay the higher price ''P''<sub>0</sub>. When the price is reduced, their benefit is the area in the rectangle formed on the top by ''P''<sub>0</sub>, on the bottom by ''P''<sub>1</sub>, on the left by the price axis and on the right by line extending vertically upwards from ''Q''<sub>0</sub>. The second set of beneficiaries are consumers who buy more, and new consumers, those who will pay the new lower price (''P''<sub>1</sub>) but not the higher price (''P''<sub>0</sub>). Their additional consumption makes up the difference between ''Q''<sub>1</sub> and ''Q''<sub>0</sub>. Their consumer surplus is the triangle bounded on the left by the line extending vertically upwards from ''Q''<sub>0</sub>, on the right and top by the demand line, and on the bottom by the line extending horizontally to the right from ''P''<sub>1</sub>. === Rule of one-half === The '''rule of one-half''' estimates the change in consumer surplus for small changes in supply with a constant demand curve. Note that in the special case where the consumer demand curve is linear, consumer surplus is the area of the triangle bounded by the vertical line ''Q'' = 0, the horizontal line <math>P = P_\mathrm{mkt}</math> and the linear demand curve. Hence, the change in consumer surplus is the area of the trapezoid with i) height equal to the change in price and ii) mid-segment length equal to the average of the ex-post and ex-ante equilibrium quantities. Following the figure above, :<math>\Delta CS = \frac{1}{2} (Q_1 + Q_0)(P_0 - P_1),</math> where: * CS = consumers' surplus; * ''Q''<sub>0</sub> and ''Q''<sub>1</sub> are, respectively, the quantity demanded before and after a change in supply; * ''P''<sub>0</sub> and ''P''<sub>1</sub> are, respectively, the prices before and after a change in supply. == Producer surplus == Producer surplus is the additional benefit that the owners of production factors and product providers bring to producers due to the differences between production, the supply price of the product, and the current market price. The difference between the amount actually obtained in a market transaction and the minimum amount it is willing to accept with the production factors or the products provided. === Calculation of producer surplus === Producer surplus is usually expressed by the area below the market price line and above the supply curve. In Figure 1, the shaded areas below the price line and above the supply curve between production zero and maximum output ''Q''<sub>1</sub> indicate producer surplus. Among them, OP<sub>1</sub>EQ<sub>1</sub> below the price line. This indicates that the total revenue is the minimum total payment actually accepted by the manufacturer. The area OP<sub>M</sub>EQ<sub>1</sub> below the S curve is the minimum total revenue that the manufacturer is willing to accept. In Figure 1, the area enclosed by the market price line, the manufacturer's supply line, and the coordinate axis is the producer surplus. Because the rectangle OP<sub>1</sub>EQ<sub>1</sub> is the total revenue actually obtained by the manufacturer, that is, ''A'' + ''B'', and the trapezoid OP<sub>M</sub>EQ. The minimum total profit that the manufacturer is willing to accept, that is, ''B'', so ''A'' is the producer surplus. [[File:Producer Surplus graph made by Weiyi.png|thumb|Producer surplus]] Obviously, the manufacturer produces and sells a certain quantity of ''Q''<sub>1</sub> goods at the market price ''P''<sub>1</sub>. The manufacturer has reduced the quantity of goods for ''Q''<sub>1</sub>, which means that the manufacturer has increased the production factors or production costs equivalent to the amount of AVCΒ·''Q''<sub>1</sub>. However, at the same time, the manufacturer actually obtains a total income equivalent to the total market price ''P''<sub>1</sub>Β·''Q''<sub>1</sub>. Since AVC is always smaller than ''P''<sub>1</sub>, from the production and sales of goods in ''Q''<sub>1</sub>, manufacturers not only get sales revenue equivalent to variable costs, but also get additional revenue. This part of the excess income reflects the increase in the benefits obtained by the manufacturers through market exchange. Therefore, in economics, producer surplus is usually used to measure producer welfare and is an important part of social welfare. Producer surplus is usually used to measure the economic welfare obtained by the manufacturer in the market supply. When the supply price is constant, the producer welfare depends on the market price. If the manufacturer can sell the product at the highest price, the welfare is the greatest. As part of social welfare, the size of the producer surplus depends on many factors. Generally speaking, when other factors remain constant, an increase in market price will increase producer surplus, and a decrease in supply price or marginal cost will also increase producer surplus. If there is a surplus of goods, that is, people can only sell part of the goods at market prices, and producer surplus will decrease. Obviously, the sum of the producer surplus of all manufacturers in the market constitutes the producer surplus of the entire market. Graphically, it should be expressed as the area enclosed by the market supply curve, the market price line and the coordinate axis. == See also == {{div col|colwidth=22em}} * [[Deadweight loss]] * [[Gross operating surplus]] * [[Induced demand]] * [[Price discrimination]] * [[Price support]] * [[Shortage]] * [[Surplus product]] * [[Surplus value]] * [[Utility]] * [[Value added]] * [[Welfare economics]] * [[Economic rent]] * [[Surplus sharing]]{{div col end}} ==References== * Bade, R., & Parkin, M. (2017). ''Essential Foundations of Economics'' (8th ed.). Pearson. * Corporate Finance Institute. (2021, March 26). ''Consumer Surplus and Producer Surplus''. <references /> ==Further reading== * [[Henry George]], ''[[Progress and Poverty]]'' * ''Modern Microeconomics'', A.Koutsyiannis * ''Microeconomic Theory, A Mathematical Approach'', James M. Henderson and Richard E. Quandt {{microeconomics-footer}} {{Authority control}} [[Category:Microeconomics]] [[Category:Welfare economics]] [[Category:Corporate finance]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:About
(
edit
)
Template:Authority control
(
edit
)
Template:Capitalism sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Cite encyclopedia
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Div col
(
edit
)
Template:Div col end
(
edit
)
Template:Microeconomics-footer
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)