Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Endogenous growth theory
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Economic theory}} {{Development economics sidebar}} {{Macroeconomics sidebar}} '''Endogenous growth theory''' holds that [[economic growth]] is primarily the result of [[Endogeneity (econometrics)|endogenous]] and not external forces.<ref>{{cite journal |journal = [[The Journal of Economic Perspectives]] |volume= 8 |issue= 1 |year= 1994 |first= P. M. |last= Romer |title= The Origins of Endogenous Growth |author-link= Paul Romer |pages =3–22 |jstor=2138148 |doi=10.1257/jep.8.1.3|doi-access= }}</ref> Endogenous growth theory holds that investment in [[human capital]], [[innovation]], and knowledge are significant contributors to economic growth. The theory also focuses on [[positive externalities]] and [[spillover effects]] of a knowledge-based economy which will lead to economic development. The endogenous growth theory primarily holds that the long run growth rate of an economy depends on policy measures. For example, [[subsidies]] for [[research and development]] or [[education]] increase the growth rate in some endogenous growth models by increasing the incentive for innovation. == Models == In the mid-1980s, a group of growth theorists became increasingly dissatisfied with common accounts of [[exogenous]] factors determining long-run growth, such as the [[Solow–Swan model]]. They favored a model that replaced the exogenous growth variable (unexplained technical progress) with a model in which the key determinants of growth were explicit in the model. The work of [[Kenneth Arrow]] (1962), {{harvs|txt|first=Hirofumi|last=Uzawa|year=1965|author-link=Hirofumi Uzawa}}, and [[Miguel Sidrauski]] (1967) formed the basis for this research.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.newschool.edu/nssr/het/essays/growth/moneygrowth.htm |title=Monetary Growth Theory |work=newschool.edu |year=2011 |access-date=11 October 2011 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20151021205217/http://www.newschool.edu/nssr/het/essays/growth/moneygrowth.htm |archive-date=21 October 2015 }}</ref> [[Paul Romer]] (1986), {{harvs|txt|first=Robert|last= Lucas|year=1988|author-link=Robert Lucas Jr.}}, {{harvs|txt|first=Sergio|last=Rebelo|year=1991|author-link=Sergio Rebelo}}<ref>{{cite web |url= http://www.econ2.jhu.edu/people/ccarroll/public/lecturenotes/Growth/RebeloAK.pdf |title= The Rebelo AK Growth Model |first= C.|last= Carroll |work=econ2.jhu.edu |year=2011 |access-date=11 October 2011 |quote= the steady-state growth rate in a Rebelo economy is directly proportional to the saving rate.}}</ref> and {{harvs|txt|last= Ortigueira|last2= Santos|year=1997}} omitted technological change; instead, growth in these models is due to indefinite investment in [[human capital]] which had a [[spillover effect]] on the economy and reduces the diminishing return to [[capital accumulation]].<ref name= "BX">{{cite book |first1= R. J. |last1= Barro |first2= Xavier |author-link2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=2nd |isbn=978-0-262-02553-9 }}</ref> The [[AK model]], which is the simplest endogenous model, gives a constant-savings rate of endogenous growth and assumes a constant, exogenous, saving rate. It models technological progress with a single parameter (usually A). The model is based on the assumption that the production function does not exhibit diminishing returns to scale. Various rationales for this assumption have been given, such as positive spillovers from capital investment to the economy as a whole or improvements in technology leading to further improvements. However, the endogenous growth theory is further supported with models in which agents optimally determined the consumption and saving, optimizing the resources allocation to research and development leading to technological progress. Romer (1986, 1990) and significant contributions by Aghion and Howitt (1992) and Grossman and Helpman (1991), incorporated [[imperfect market]]s and R&D to the growth model.<ref name= "BX"/> === AK model === {{main|AK model}} The AK model production function is a special case of a [[Cobb–Douglas production function]]: : <math>Y=AK^aL^{1-a}\,</math> This equation shows a Cobb–Douglas function where ''Y'' represents the total production in an economy. ''A'' represents [[total factor productivity]], ''K'' is capital, ''L'' is labor, and the parameter <math>a</math> measures the [[output elasticity]] of capital. For the special case in which <math>a = 1</math>, the production function becomes linear in capital thereby giving [[constant returns to scale]]:<ref name= "BX"/> : <math>Y=AK.</math> == Versus exogenous growth theory == In neo-classical growth models, the long-run rate of growth is [[exogenous variable|exogenously]] determined by either the savings rate (the [[Harrod–Domar model]]) or the rate of technical progress ([[Solow model]]). However, the savings rate and rate of technological progress remain unexplained. Endogenous growth theory tries to overcome this shortcoming by building macroeconomic models out of [[Microfoundations|microeconomic foundations]]. Households are assumed to maximize utility subject to budget constraints while firms maximize profits. Crucial importance is usually given to the production of new technologies and [[human capital]]. The engine for growth can be as simple as a constant return to scale production function (the AK model) or more complicated set ups with [[Knowledge spillover|spillover]] effects (spillovers are positive externalities, benefits that are attributed to costs from other firms), increasing numbers of goods, increasing qualities, etc.{{cn|date=February 2024}} Often endogenous growth theory assumes constant marginal product of capital at the aggregate level, or at least that the limit of the marginal product of capital does not tend towards zero. This does not imply that larger firms will be more productive than small ones, because at the firm level the marginal product of capital is still diminishing. Therefore, it is possible to construct endogenous growth models with [[perfect competition]]. However, in many endogenous growth models the assumption of perfect competition is relaxed, and some degree of [[monopoly]] power is thought to exist. Generally monopoly power in these models comes from the holding of patents. These are models with two sectors, producers of final output and an R&D sector: the R&D sector develops ideas which grant them monopoly power. R&D firms are assumed to be able to make monopoly profits selling ideas to production firms, but the [[free entry]] condition means that these profits are dissipated on R&D spending.{{cn|date=February 2024}} == Implications == An endogenous growth theory implication is that policies that embrace openness, competition, change and innovation will promote growth.{{cn|date=December 2019}} Conversely, policies that have the effect of restricting or slowing change by protecting or favouring particular existing industries or firms are likely, over time, to slow growth to the disadvantage of the community. [[Peter Howitt (economist)|Peter Howitt]] has written: <blockquote> Sustained economic growth is everywhere and always a process of continual transformation. The sort of economic progress that has been enjoyed by the richest nations since the Industrial Revolution would not have been possible if people had not undergone wrenching changes. Economies that cease to transform themselves are destined to fall off the path of economic growth. The countries that most deserve the title of "developing" are not the poorest countries of the world, but the richest. [They] need to engage in the never-ending process of economic development if they are to enjoy continued prosperity.<ref>{{cite book| publisher= [[C. D. Howe Institute]] | title= Growth and development: a Schumpeterian perspective| journal= C. D. Howe Institute Commentary| url= http://www.cdhowe.org/pdf/commentary_246.pdf| archive-url= https://web.archive.org/web/20110717090449/http://www.cdhowe.org/pdf/commentary_246.pdf| url-status= dead| first= Peter | last= Howitt| author-link= Peter Howitt (economist)| number= 246| date= April 2007| isbn= 978-0888067098 |issn= 0824-8001| archive-date= July 17, 2011| access-date= August 16, 2018}}</ref> </blockquote> == Criticisms ==<!-- This section is linked from [[Economics]] --> One of the main failings of endogenous growth theories is the collective failure to explain [[convergence (economics)|conditional convergence]] reported in empirical literature.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Sachs |first1=Jeffrey D. |first2=Andrew M. |last2= Warner |year=1997 |title=Fundamental Sources of Long-Run Growth |journal=[[American Economic Review]] |volume=87 |issue=2 |pages= 184–188 |jstor=2950910 }}</ref> Another frequent critique concerns the cornerstone assumption of diminishing returns to capital. Stephen Parente contends that new growth theory has proved to be no more successful than [[neoclassical growth model|exogenous growth theory]] in explaining the income divergence between the [[developing nation|developing]] and [[developed nation|developed]] worlds (despite usually being more complex).<ref>{{cite journal |last=Parente |first=Stephen |title=The Failure of Endogenous Growth |journal=Knowledge, Technology & Policy |year=2001 |volume=13 |issue=4 |pages=49–58 |doi=10.1007/BF02693989 |citeseerx=10.1.1.471.9285 |s2cid=153333748 }}</ref> [[Paul Krugman]] criticized endogenous growth theory as nearly impossible to check by [[empirical evidence]]; "too much of it involved making assumptions about how unmeasurable things affected other unmeasurable things."<ref>{{cite news |url=https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2013/08/18/the-new-growth-fizzle/?_r=0 |title=The New Growth Fizzle |newspaper=New York Times |first=Paul |last=Krugman |date=August 18, 2013 }}</ref> == See also == * [[Economic growth]] * [[Human capital]] * [[Feldman–Mahalanobis model]] * [[Solow–Swan model]], "the" exogenous growth model * [[Ramsey–Cass–Koopmans model]], a microfounded growth model with infinite horizon == Notes == {{reflist}} == References == * {{cite journal |url= http://www.fordham.edu/economics/mcleod/LucasMechanicsEconomicGrowth.pdf |title= On the mechanics of Economic Development |first= R. E. |last= Lucas |author-link= Robert Emerson Lucas Jr. |journal = [[Journal of Monetary Economics]] |year=1988 |volume = 22 |pages= 3–42 |doi= 10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7 |s2cid= 154875771 }} * {{cite journal |title= On the Speed of Convergence in Endogenous Growth Models |first1= Salvador |last1= Ortigueira |first2= Manuel S. |last2= Santos |journal = [[American Economic Review]] |year=1997 |volume = 87 |issue= 3 |pages= 383–399 |jstor=2951351 }} * {{cite journal |title= Long-Run Policy Analysis and Long-Run Growth |first= Sergio |last= Rebelo |journal = [[Journal of Political Economy]] |year=1991 |volume = 99 |issue= 3 |page= 500 |doi=10.1086/261764 |citeseerx=10.1.1.295.3609 |s2cid= 14215251 }} * {{Cite journal |first=Hirofumi |last=Uzawa |title=Optimum Technical Change in an Aggregative Model of Economic Growth |journal=[[International Economic Review]] |volume=6 |issue=1 |year=1965 |pages=18–31 |url =http://kisi.deu.edu.tr/yesim.kustepeli/uzawa1965.pdf |doi=10.2307/2525621 |jstor=2525621 }} == Further reading == * {{cite book |first=Daron |last=Acemoglu |author-link=Daron Acemoglu |chapter=Endogenous Technological Change |title=Introduction to Modern Economic Growth |url=https://archive.org/details/introductiontomo00acem |url-access=limited |publisher=Princeton University Press |year=2009 |isbn=978-0-691-13292-1 |pages=[https://archive.org/details/introductiontomo00acem/page/n423 411]–533 }} * Akcigit, Ufuk; Ates, Sina T. (2021/01). "[https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/mac.20180449 Ten Facts on Declining Business Dynamism and Lessons from Endogenous Growth Theory]". ''American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics'' 13(1): 257–298. * {{cite book |first1= Robert J. |last1= Barro |author-link1=Robert J. Barro |first2= Xavier |author-link2= Xavier Sala-i-Martin |last2= Sala-i-Martin |chapter=One-Sector Models of Endogenous Growth |title=Economic Growth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2004 |edition=Second |isbn=978-0-262-02553-9 |pages=205–237 }} * {{cite book |last=Farmer |first=Roger E. A. |chapter=Endogenous Growth Theory |title=Macroeconomics |location=Cincinnati |publisher=South-Western |year=1999 |edition=Second |isbn=978-0-324-12058-5 |pages=357–380 }} * {{cite book |first=David |last=Romer |author-link=David Romer |chapter=Endogenous Growth |title=Advanced Macroeconomics |edition=Fourth |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |year=2011 |pages=101–149 |isbn=978-0-07-351137-5 }} {{Economics}} [[Category:Macroeconomic theories]] [[Category:Economic growth]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite news
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Cn
(
edit
)
Template:Development economics sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Economics
(
edit
)
Template:Harvs
(
edit
)
Template:Macroeconomics sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Main
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)