Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Endowment effect
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Cognitive bias}} In [[psychology]] and [[behavioral economics]], the '''endowment effect''', also known as '''divestiture aversion''', is the finding that people are more likely to retain an object they own than acquire that same object when they do not own it.<ref name="Roeckelein2006">{{cite book |first=J. E. |last=Roeckelein |title=Elsevier's Dictionary of Psychological Theories |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=1Yn6NZgxvssC&pg=PA147 |year=2006 |publisher=Elsevier |isbn=978-0-08-046064-2 |page=147 }}</ref><ref name="Morewedge2015"/><ref name=":1"/><ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler"/> The endowment theory can be defined as "an application of prospect theory positing that loss aversion associated with ownership explains observed exchange asymmetries."<ref name="Zeiler 1449β1466">{{Cite journal |last=Zeiler |first=Kathryn |date=September 2007 |title=Exchange Asymmetries Incorrectly Interpreted as Evidence of Endowment Effect Theory and Prospect Theory?|url=https://scholarship.law.bu.edu/faculty_scholarship/454 |journal=American Economic Review |volume=97 |issue=4 |pages=1449β1466 |doi=10.1257/aer.97.4.1449 |doi-access=free |s2cid=16803164|url-access=subscription }}</ref> This is typically illustrated in two ways.<ref name="Morewedge2015">{{Cite journal |title=Explanations of the endowment effect: an integrative review |journal=Trends in Cognitive Sciences |date=2015 |pages=339β348 |volume=19 |issue=6 |doi=10.1016/j.tics.2015.04.004 |pmid=25939336 |first1=Carey K. |last1=Morewedge |first2=Colleen E. |last2=Giblin |s2cid=4619648}}</ref> In a valuation paradigm, people's maximum [[willingness to pay]] (WTP) to acquire an object is typically lower than the least amount they are [[Willingness to accept|willing to accept]] (WTA) to give up that same object when they own itβeven when there is no cause for attachment, or even if the item was only obtained minutes ago.<ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler"/> In an exchange paradigm, people given a good are reluctant to trade it for another good of similar value. For example, participants first given a pen of equal expected value to that of a coffee mug were generally unwilling to trade, whilst participants first given the coffee mug were also unwilling to trade it for the pen.<ref name="KKT91"/> A more controversial third paradigm used to elicit the endowment effect is the [[Mere ownership effect|mere ownership]] paradigm, primarily used in experiments in psychology, marketing, and organizational behavior. In this paradigm, people who are randomly assigned to receive a good ("owners") evaluate it more positively than people who are not randomly assigned to receive the good ("[[Treatment and control groups|controls]]").<ref name=":0">{{Cite journal |last=Beggan |first=J. |date=1992 |title=On the social nature of nonsocial perception: The mere ownership effect |journal=Journal of Personality and Social Psychology |volume=62 |issue=2 |pages=229β237 |doi=10.1037/0022-3514.62.2.229}}</ref><ref name="Morewedge2015"/> The distinction between this paradigm and the first two is that it is not [[incentive compatibility|incentive-compatible]]. In other words, participants are not explicitly incentivized to reveal the extent to which they truly like or value the good. The endowment effect can be equated to the behavioural model [[willingness to accept|willingness to accept or pay (WTAP)]], a formula sometimes used to find out how much a consumer or person is willing to put up with or lose for different outcomes. However, this model has come under recent criticism as potentially inaccurate.<ref name="Zeiler 1449β1466"/><ref name="Zeiler 530β545">{{Cite journal|last1=Plott |first1=Charles |last2=Zeiler |first2=Kathryn |author-link2=Kathryn Zeiler |date=June 2005 |title=The Willingness to Pay-Willingness to Accept Gap, the 'Endowment Effect,' Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations |url=https://scholarship.law.bu.edu/faculty_scholarship/781 |journal=American Economic Review |volume=95 |issue=3 |pages=530β545 |doi=10.1257/0002828054201387 |doi-access=free}}</ref> ==Examples== One of the most famous examples of the endowment effect in the literature is from a study by [[Daniel Kahneman]], Jack Knetsch & [[Richard Thaler]],<ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler"/> in which [[Cornell University]] undergraduates were given a mug and then offered the chance to sell it or trade it for an equally valued alternative (pens). They found that the amount participants required as compensation for the mug once their ownership of the mug had been established ("willingness to accept") was approximately twice as high as the amount they were willing to pay to acquire the mug ("willingness to pay"). Other examples of the endowment effect include work by [[Ziv Carmon]] and [[Dan Ariely]],<ref name="Carmon" /> who found that participants' hypothetical selling price ([[willingness to accept]] or WTA) for NCAA final four tournament tickets were 14 times higher than their hypothetical buying price ([[willingness to pay]] or WTP). Also, work by Hossain and List (Working Paper) discussed in the Economist in 2010,<ref name="Carrots" /> showed that workers worked harder to maintain ownership of a provisionally awarded bonus than they did for a bonus framed as a potential yet-to-be-awarded gain. In addition to these examples, the endowment effect has been observed using different goods<ref name="Hoffman" /> in a wide range of different populations, including children,<ref name="Harbaugh" /> great apes,<ref name="Kanngiesser" /> and new world monkeys.<ref name="Lakshminaryanan" /> ==Background== The endowment effect has been observed from ancient times: {{blockquote|text=For most things are differently valued by those who have them and by those who wish to get them: what belongs to us, and what we give away, always seems very precious to us.|author=Aristotle|source=[[The Nicomachean Ethics]] book IX (F. H. Peters translation)}} Psychologists first noted the difference between consumers' WTP and WTA as early as the 1960s.<ref name="Coombs" /><ref name=SlovicLichtenstein1968 /> The term ''endowment effect'' however was first explicitly coined in 1980 by the economist [[Richard Thaler]] in reference to the under-weighting of [[opportunity costs]] as well as the inertia introduced into a consumer's choice processes when goods included in their endowment become more highly valued than goods that are not.<ref name="Thaler" /> At the time Thaler's conceptualisation of the endowment effect was in direct contrast to that of accepted economic theory, which assumed humans were completely rational when making decisions. Through his contrasting viewpoint, Thaler was able to offer a clearer understanding of how humans make economic decisions.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Landy |first=Frank J. |date=2005 |title=Some historical and scientific issues related to research on emotional intelligence |url=http://dx.doi.org/10.1002/job.317 |journal=Journal of Organizational Behavior |volume=26 |issue=4 |pages=411β424 |doi=10.1002/job.317 |issn=0894-3796|url-access=subscription }}</ref> In the years that followed, extensive investigations into the endowment effect have been conducted producing a wealth of interesting empirical and theoretical findings.<ref name="Hoffman" /> ==Theoretical explanations== ===Loss aversion=== The leading explanation for the aforementioned WTP-WTA gap is that of loss aversion. It was first linked by Kahneman and his colleagues that selling an endowment means the loss of the object, and as humans are aligned to be more [[Loss aversion|loss-averse]], less utility is obtained from acquirement of the same endowment.<ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler" /> They go on to suggest that the endowment effect, when considered as a facet of loss-aversion, would thus violate the [[Coase theorem]], and was described as inconsistent with standard [[economic]] theory which asserts that a person's [[willingness to pay]] (WTP) for a good should be equal to their [[willingness to accept]] (WTA) compensation to be deprived of the good, a hypothesis which underlies [[consumer theory]] and [[indifference curves]]. Another aspect of loss aversion exhibited within the endowment effect is that opportunity costs are often undervalued. The overcharging of the selling item stems from the fixation of losing the item rather than the unattained gain if the sale falls through.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Thaler |first=Richard |date=1980-03-01 |title=Toward a positive theory of consumer choice |url=https://dx.doi.org/10.1016/0167-2681%2880%2990051-7 |journal=Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization |language=en |volume=1 |issue=1 |pages=39β60 |doi=10.1016/0167-2681(80)90051-7 |s2cid=39532776 |issn=0167-2681|url-access=subscription }}</ref> The correlation between the two theories is so high that the endowment effect is often seen as the presentation of loss aversion in a riskless setting. However, these claims have been disputed and other researchers claim that [[psychological inertia]],<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Gal |first1=David |last2=Rucker |first2=Derek D. |date=2018 |title=The Loss of Loss Aversion: Will It Loom Larger Than Its Gain?|journal=Journal of Consumer Psychology |language=en |volume=28 |issue=3 |pages=497β516 |doi=10.1002/jcpy.1047 |s2cid=148956334 |issn=1532-7663|doi-access=free }}</ref> differences in reference prices relied on by buyers and sellers,<ref name=":1"/> and ownership (attribution of the item to self) and not loss aversion are the key to this phenomenon.<ref name="Morewedge2009"/> ===Psychological inertia=== [[David Gal]] proposed a [[psychological inertia]] account of the endowment effect.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Gal |first=David |date=July 2006 |title=A Psychological Law of Inertia and the Illusion of Loss Aversion |journal=Judgment and Decision Making |volume=1 |pages=23β32 |url=http://www.sjdm.org/~baron/journal/jdm06002.pdf |doi=10.1017/S1930297500000322}}</ref><ref>{{Cite news |url=https://www.nytimes.com/2018/10/06/opinion/sunday/behavioral-economics.html |title=Opinion {{!}} Why Is Behavioral Economics So Popular? |last=Gal |first=David |date=2018-10-06 |work=The New York Times |access-date=2019-04-05 |language=en-US |issn=0362-4331}}</ref> In this account, sellers require a higher price to part with an object than buyers are willing to pay because neither has a well-defined, precise valuation for the object and therefore there is a range of prices over which neither buyers nor sellers have much incentive to trade. For example, in the case of Kahneman et al.'s (1990) classic mug experiments (where sellers demanded about $7 to part with their mug whereas buyers were only willing to pay, on average, about $3 to acquire a mug) there was likely a range of prices for the mug ($4 to $6) that left the buyers and sellers without much incentive to either acquire or part with it. Buyers and sellers therefore maintained the status quo out of inertia. Conversely, a high price ($7 or more) yielded a meaningful incentive for an owner to part with the mug; likewise, a relatively low price ($3 or less) yielded a meaningful incentive for a buyer to acquire the mug. ===Reference-dependent accounts=== According to [[Reference dependence|reference-dependent]] theories, consumers first evaluate the potential change in question as either being a gain or a loss. In line with [[prospect theory]] (Tversky and Kahneman, 1979<ref name="KahnemanTversky1979" />), changes that are framed as losses are weighed more heavily than are the changes framed as gains. Thus an individual owning "A" amount of a good, asked how much he/she would be willing to pay to acquire "B", would be willing to pay a value (B-A) that is lower than the value that he/she would be willing to accept to sell (C-A) units; the value function for perceived gains is not as steep as the value function for perceived losses. Figure 1 presents this explanation in graphical form. An individual at point A, asked how much he/she would be willing to accept (WTA) as compensation to sell X units and move to point C, would demand greater compensation for that loss than he/she would be willing to pay for an equivalent gain of X units to move him/her to point B. Thus the difference between (B-A) and (C-A) would account for the endowment effect. In other words, he/she expects more money while selling; but wants to pay less while buying the same amount of goods. :[[File:ValunFunProspectTheory2.png]] :''Figure 1: Prospect Theory and the Endowment Effect'' ===Neoclassical explanations=== Hanemann (1991),<ref name="Hanemann" /> develops a [[neoclassical economic theory|neoclassical]] explanation for the endowment effect, accounting for the effect without invoking [[prospect theory]]. Figure 2 presents this explanation in graphical form. In the figure, two [[indifference curves]] for a particular good X and wealth are given. Consider an individual who is given goods X such that they move from point A (where they have X<sub>0</sub> of good X) to point B (where they have the same wealth and X<sub>1</sub> of good X). Their WTP represented by the vertical distance from B to C, because (after giving up that amount of wealth) the individual is indifferent about being at A or C. Now consider an individual who gives up goods such that they move from B to A. Their WTA represented by the (larger) vertical distance from A to D because (after receiving that much wealth) they are indifferent about either being at point B or D. Shogren et al. (1994)<ref name="Shogren" /> has reported findings that lend support to Hanemann's hypothesis. However, Kahneman, Knetsch, and Thaler (1991)<ref name="KKT91" /> find that the endowment effect continues even when wealth effects are fully controlled for. :[[File:Simple-indifference-curves-2.png]] :''Figure 2: Hanemann's Endowment Effect Explanation'' When goods are indivisible, a coalitional game can be set up so that a utility function can be defined on all subsets of the goods. Hu (2020)<ref>{{cite journal |last=Hu |first=Xingwei |year=2020 |title=A theory of dichotomous valuation with applications to variable selection |journal=Econometric Reviews |volume=39 |issue=10 |pages=1075β1099 |doi=10.1080/07474938.2020.1735750 |arxiv=1808.00131 |s2cid=32184598}}</ref> shows the endowment effect when the utility function is [[superadditive]], i.e., the value of the whole is greater than the sum of its parts. Hu (2020) also introduces a few unbiased solutions which mitigate endowment bias. Experiments in cognitive psychology have demonstrated that the endowment effect can be brought about by asymmetries in cognitive processing in judging owned and not-owned goods. A 2007 fMRI study by Knutson et al. demonstrated that the insula, an area of the brain associated with loss aversion, is stimulated when people ponder relinquishing goods they already possess. This is consistent with the hypothesis that the endowment effect entails not only ownership bias but also emotional attachment and loss anticipation neural processes. Further, the effect is also conditioned by cultural environment and personality difference in risk sensitivity. <ref>Knutson, B., Rick, S., Wimmer, G. E., Prelec, D., & Loewenstein, G. (2007). Neural predictors of purchases. Neuron, 53(1), 147β156. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.neuron.2006.11.010</ref> ===Connection-based, or "psychological ownership" theories=== Connection-based theories propose that the attachment or association with the self-induced by owning a good is responsible for the endowment effect (for a review, see Morewedge & Giblin, 2015<ref name="Morewedge2015"/>). Work by Morewedge, Shu, Gilbert and Wilson (2009)<ref name="Morewedge2009"/> provides support for these theories, as does work by Maddux et al. (2010).<ref name=Maddux/> For example, research participants who were given one mug and asked how much they would pay for a second mug ("owner-buyers") were WTP as much as "owners-sellers," another group of participants who were given a mug and asked how much they were WTA to sell it (both groups valued the mug in question more than buyers who were not given a mug).<ref name="Morewedge2009"/> Others have argued that the short duration of ownership or highly prosaic items typically used in endowment effect type studies is not sufficient to produce such a connection, conducting research demonstrating support for those points (e.g. Liersch & Rottenstreich, Working Paper). Two paths by which attachment or self-associations increase the value of a good have been proposed (Morewedge & Giblin, 2015).<ref name="Morewedge2015"/> An [[attachment theory]] suggests that ownership creates a non-transferable balanced association between the self and the good. The good is incorporated into the self-concept of the owner, becoming part of her identity and imbuing it with attributes related to her self-concept. Self-associations may take the form of an emotional attachment to the good. Once an attachment has formed, the potential loss of the good is perceived as a threat to the self.<ref name=":0"/> A real-world example of this would be an individual refusing to part with a college T-shirt because it supports one's identity as an alumnus of that university. A second route by which ownership may increase value is through a [[Self-referential encoding|self-referential memory effect]] (SRE) β the better encoding and recollection of stimuli associated with the self-concept.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Symons |first1=Cynthia S. |last2=Johnson |first2=Blair T. |title=The self-reference effect in memory: A meta-analysis |journal=Psychological Bulletin |date=1997 |volume=121 |issue=3 |pages=371β394 |doi=10.1037/0033-2909.121.3.371 |url=https://opencommons.uconn.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1008&context=chip_docs |pmid=9136641|url-access=subscription }}</ref> People have a better memory for goods they own than goods they do not own. The self-referential memory effect for owned goods may act thus as an endogenous framing effect. During a transaction, attributes of a good may be more accessible to its owners than are other attributes of the transaction. Because most goods have more positive than negative features, this accessibility bias should result in owners more positively evaluating their goods than do non-owners.<ref name="Morewedge2015"/> === Greater sensitivity to market demands for sellers === Sellers may dictate a price based on the desires of multiple potential buyers, whereas buyers may consider their own taste. This can lead to differences between buying and selling prices because the market price is typically higher than one's idiosyncratic price estimate. According to this account, the endowment effect can be viewed as under-pricing for buyers compared to the market price; or over-pricing for sellers compared to their individual taste. Two recent lines of study support this argument. Weaver and Frederick (2012) <ref name=":1">{{cite journal |last1=Weaver |first1=R. |last2=Frederick |first2=S.|title= A Reference Price Theory of the Endowment Effect |journal=Journal of Marketing Research |date=2012 |volume=49 |issue=5 |pages=696β707 |doi=10.1509/jmr.09.0103 |s2cid=412119}}</ref> presented their participants with retail prices of products, and then asked them to specify either their buying or selling price for these products. The results revealed that sellers' valuations were closer to the known retail prices than those of buyers. A second line of studies is a meta-analysis of buying and selling of lotteries.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Yechiam |first1=Eldad. |last2=Ashby |first2=Nathaniel J.S. |last3=Pachur |first3=Thorsten |title=Who's biased? A meta-analysis of buyer-seller differences in the pricing of risky prospects |journal=Psychological Bulletin |date=2017 |volume=143 |issue=5 |pages=543β563 |doi=10.1037/bul0000095 |pmid=28263644 |s2cid=33771796}}</ref> A review of over 30 empirical studies showed that selling prices were closer to the lottery's expected value, which is the normative price of the lottery: hence the endowment effect was consistent with buyers' tendency to under-price lotteries as compared to the normative price. One possible reason for this tendency of buyers to indicate lower prices is their risk aversion. By contrast, sellers may assume that the market is heterogeneous enough to include buyers with potential risk neutrality and therefore adjust their price closer to a risk neutral expected value. === Biased information processing theories === Several cognitive accounts of the endowment effect suggest that it is induced by the way endowment status changes the search for, attention to, recollection of, and weighting of information regarding the transaction. Frames evoked by acquisition of a good (e.g., buying, choosing it rather than another good) may increase the cognitive [[Spreading activation|accessibility]] of information favoring the decision to keep one's money and not acquire the good. By contrast, frames evoked by disposition of the good (e.g., selling) may increase the cognitive accessibility of information favoring the decision to keep the good rather than trade or dispose of it for money (for a review, see Morewedge & Giblin, 2015).<ref name="Morewedge2015" /> For example, [[Query theory|Johnson and colleagues]] (2007)<ref>{{cite journal|last1=Johnson|first1=Eric J. |last2=HΓ€ubl |first2=Gerald |last3=Keinan |first3=Anat |title=Aspects of endowment: A query theory of value construction |journal=Journal of Experimental Psychology: Learning, Memory, and Cognition |date=2007 |volume=33 |issue=3 |pages=461β474 |doi=10.1037/0278-7393.33.3.461 |pmid=17470000 |s2cid=9699491}}</ref> found that prospective mug buyers tended to recall reasons to keep their money before recalling reasons to buy the mug, whereas sellers tended to recall reasons to keep their mug before reasons to sell it for money. ===Evolutionary arguments=== Huck, Kirchsteiger & Oechssler (2005)<ref name="Huck"/> have raised the hypothesis that natural selection may favor individuals whose preferences embody an endowment effect given that it may improve one's bargaining position in bilateral trades. Thus in a small tribal society with a few alternative sellers (i.e. where the buyer may not have the option of moving to an alternative seller), having a predisposition towards embodying the endowment effect may be evolutionarily beneficial. This may be linked with findings (Shogren, et al., 1994<ref name="Shogren"/>) that suggest the endowment effect is less strong when the relatively artificial sense of scarcity induced in experimental settings is lessened. Countervailing evidence for an evolutionary account is provided by studies showing that the endowment effect is moderated by exposure to modern exchange markets (e.g., hunter gatherer tribes with market exposure are more likely to exhibit the endowment effect than tribes that do not),<ref>{{Cite journal |title=Evolutionary Origins of the Endowment Effect: Evidence from Hunter-Gatherers |date=2014 |url=https://dash.harvard.edu/bitstream/1/33839947/1/aer.104.6.1793.pdf |journal=American Economic Review |pages=1793β1805 |volume=104 |issue=6 |doi=10.1257/aer.104.6.1793 |first1=Coren L. |last1=Apicella |first2=Eduardo M. |last2=Azevedo |first3=Nicholas A. |last3=Christakis |first4=James H. |last4=Fowler}}</ref> and that the endowment effect is moderated by culture (Maddux et al., 2010<ref name="Maddux"/>). ==Criticisms== Some economists have questioned the effect's existence.<ref name="Zeiler 530β545"/><ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Klass |first1=Greg |author2-link=Kathryn Zeiler |last2=Zeiler |first2=Kathryn |date=2013 |title=Against Endowment Theory: Experimental Economics and Legal Scholarship |url=https://scholarship.law.bu.edu/faculty_scholarship/199 |journal=UCLA Law Review |volume=61 |issue=1 |pages=2β64 |ssrn=2224105 |doi=10.2139/ssrn.2224105 |s2cid=35058914 |id=Georgetown Public Law Research Paper No. 13-013, Georgetown Law and Economics Research Paper No. 13-005|url-access=subscription }}</ref> Hanemann (1991)<ref name="Hanemann"/> noted that [[economic theory]] only suggests that WTP and WTA should be equal for goods which are close substitutes, so observed differences in these measures for goods such as environmental resources and personal health can be explained without reference to an endowment effect. Shogren, et al. (1994)<ref name="Shogren"/> noted that the experimental technique used by Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler (1990)<ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler"/> to demonstrate the endowment effect created a situation of artificial scarcity. They performed a more robust experiment with the same goods used by Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler (chocolate bars and mugs) and found little evidence of the endowment effect in substitutable goods, acknowledging the endowment effect as valid for goods without substitutesβnon-renewable Earth resources being an example of these. Others have argued that the use of hypothetical questions and experiments involving small amounts of money tells us little about actual behavior (e.g. Hoffman and Spitzer, 1993, p. 69, n. 23<ref name="Hoffman"/>) with some research supporting these points (e.g., Kahneman, Knetsch and Thaler, 1990,<ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler"/> Harless, 1989<ref name="Harless"/>) and others not (e.g. Knez, Smith and Williams, 1985<ref name="Knez" />). More recently, [[Charles Plott|Plott]] and [[Kathryn Zeiler|Zeiler]] have challenged the endowment effect theory by arguing that observed disparities between [[Willingness to accept|WTA]] and [[Willingness-to-pay|WTP]] measures are not reflective of human preferences, but rather such disparities stem from faulty experimental designs.<ref name="Zeiler 530β545"/><ref>{{Cite journal |last=Plott |first=Charles |date=April 2011 |title=The Willingness to Pay-Willingness to Accept Gap, the 'Endowment Effect,' Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations: Reply |url=https://scholarship.law.bu.edu/faculty_scholarship/521 |journal=American Economic Review |volume=101 |issue=2 |pages=1012β1028 |doi=10.1257/aer.101.2.1012 |doi-access=free}}</ref> ==Implications== Implications regarding the endowment effect are present at both the individual and corporate level. Its presence can cause market inefficiencies and value irregularities between buyers and sellers with similar consequences at smaller or upscaled transactions.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Brackett |first1=Marc A |last2=Mayer |first2=John D |last3=Warner |first3=Rebecca M |date=April 2004 |title=Emotional intelligence and its relation to everyday behaviour |journal=Personality and Individual Differences |volume=36 |issue=6 |pages=1387β1402 |doi=10.1016/s0191-8869(03)00236-8 |issn=0191-8869}}</ref> === Individual === [[Herbert Hovenkamp]] (1991)<ref name="Hovenkamp" /> has argued that the presence of an endowment effect has significant implications for [[law]] and [[economics]], particularly in regard to [[welfare economics]]. He argues that the presence of an endowment effect indicates that a person has no [[indifference curve]] (see however Hanemann, 1991<ref name="Hanemann" />) rendering the neoclassical tools of welfare analysis useless, concluding that courts should instead use WTA as a measure of value. Fischel (1995)<ref name="Fischel" /> however, raises the counterpoint that using WTA as a measure of value would deter the development of a nation's infrastructure and [[economic growth]]. The endowment effect changes the shape of the indifference curves substantially<ref>{{Citation|url=http://docplayer.net/46319513-Behavioural-indifference-curves.html |title="Behavioral Indifference Curves," Australasian Journal of Economics Education. 2015, 2: 1β11}}</ref> Similarly, another study that is focused on the Strategic Reallocations for Endowment analyses how it is the case that economics's agents welfare could potentially increase if they change their endowment holding. Further to this, the endowment effect has been linked to both economic and psychological impacts of various scale. For example, often individuals refuse the sale of their house or upscale their expected value simply due to their emotional attachment and effort poured into it. This means they might either stick with a property which causes greater inconvenience to alternatives or have an increased level of difficulties associated with its sale.<ref name="Huck" /> Either of these scenarios both negatively impact the relevant economy and the individual's mental welfare. Alternatively, if a buyer is subject to purchasing the item at the WTA level when it is set above market price, they are subject to overspending which positively impacts the economy whilst potentially reducing individual welfare yet again. === Business === In recent years the endowment effect has largely been leveraged within e-commerce. Businesses have expanded more rapidly than previous years through its effective integration into marketing products and services.<ref>{{Cite web |last1=Model |first1=Slide |last2=admin |date=2020-06-30 |title=How the Endowment Effect can Affect Businesses |url=https://slidemodel.com/endowment-effect-and-businesses/ |access-date=2023-04-24 |website=SlideModel |language=en-US}}</ref> Here consumers are often given a sense of ownership over what the business possesses thereby unlocking the cognitive bias. ==== Free trials ==== By offering free trials to select services, business not only expand the number of users reached, but during this trial period they also give consumers a sense of ownership.<ref name=":2">{{Cite web |title=Endowment Effect |url=https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/wealth-management/endowment-effect/ |access-date=2023-04-24 |website=Corporate Finance Institute |language=en-US}}</ref> Consumer's psychological perception thus makes them more reluctant to part with the service when the trial ends, thereby increasing the quantity of subscribers. ==== Free return ==== This marketing strategy makes consumers more likely to purchase the product due to the perception of it being more endowing. However, once purchased, customers are less inclined to return it even if a level of dissatisfaction was experienced.<ref name=":2" /> ==== Haptic imagery ==== Various businesses offer a sense of ownership through showing customers what their product might look like in a relatable environment.<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal |last1=Peck |first1=Joann |last2=Barger |first2=Victor A. |last3=Webb |first3=Andrea |date=2013-04-01 |title=In search of a surrogate for touch: The effect of haptic imagery on perceived ownership |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S1057740812001192 |journal=Journal of Consumer Psychology |language=en |volume=23 |issue=2 |pages=189β196 |doi=10.1016/j.jcps.2012.09.001 |issn=1057-7408|url-access=subscription }}</ref> Fashion and furniture businesses largely rely on haptic imagery to sell their products. While they do not necessarily offer customers to use their products they create an image of what could be, by either offering online viewing adjustments or appealing to ones sense of imagination.<ref name=":3" /> This feeling of ownership makes it harder for consumers to let go of the image and thus the product. ==See also== {{portal|Psychology}} * [[Escalation of commitment]] * [[Mere ownership effect]] * [[Loss aversion]] * [[Omission bias]] * [[Behavioral economics]] * [[List of cognitive biases]] * [[Sunk costs]] * [[Transaction cost]] * [[IKEA effect]] ==References== {{Reflist|32em|refs= <ref name="Thaler">{{cite journal|last1=Thaler|first1=Richard|title=Toward a positive theory of consumer choice|journal=Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization|volume=1|issue=1|year=1980|pages=39β60|doi=10.1016/0167-2681(80)90051-7|s2cid=39532776 }}</ref> <ref name="Shogren">{{cite journal|last1=Shogren|first1=Jason F.|last2=Shin|first2=Seung Y.|last3=Hayes|first3=Dermot J.|last4=Kliebenstein|first4=James B.|title=Resolving Differences in Willingness to Pay and Willingness to Accept|journal=American Economic Review|date=1994|volume=84|issue=1|pages=255β270|jstor=2117981}}</ref> <ref name="Hanemann">{{cite journal|last1=Hanemann|first1=W. Michael|title=Willingness To Pay and Willingness To Accept: How Much Can They Differ? Reply|journal=American Economic Review|volume=81|issue=3|year=1991|pages=635β647|jstor=2006525|doi=10.1257/000282803321455449}}</ref> <ref name="Carmon">{{cite journal|last1=Carmon|first1=Ziv|last2=Ariely|first2=Dan|title=Focusing on the Forgone: How Value Can Appear So Different to Buyers and Sellers|journal=Journal of Consumer Research|volume=27|issue=3|year=2000|pages=360β370|doi=10.1086/317590}}</ref> <ref name="KahnemanKnetschThaler">{{cite journal|title=Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem|journal=Journal of Political Economy|volume=98|issue=6|pages=1325β1348|year=1990|jstor=2937761|doi=10.1086/261737|last1=Kahneman|first1=Daniel|last2=Knetsch|first2=Jack L.|last3=Thaler|first3=Richard H.|s2cid=154889372|doi-access=free}}</ref> <ref name="Harbaugh">{{cite journal|last1=Harbaugh|first1=William T|last2=Krause|first2=Kate|last3=Vesterlund|first3=Lise|title=Are adults better behaved than children? Age, experience, and the endowment effect|journal=Economics Letters|volume=70|issue=2|year=2001|pages=175β181|doi=10.1016/S0165-1765(00)00359-1|citeseerx=10.1.1.233.812}}</ref> <ref name="Lakshminaryanan">{{cite journal|last1=Lakshminaryanan|first1=V.|last2=Chen|first2=M. K.|last3=Santos|first3=L. R|title=Endowment effect in capuchin monkeys|journal=Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences|volume=363|issue=1511|year=2008|pages=3837β3844|doi=10.1098/rstb.2008.0149|pmc=2581778|pmid=18840573}}</ref> <ref name="Coombs">{{cite journal|last1=Coombs|first1=C.H.|last2=Bezembinder|first2=T.G.|last3=Goode|first3=F.M.|title=Testing expectation theories of decision making without measuring utility or subjective probability|journal=Journal of Mathematical Psychology|volume=4|issue=1|year=1967|pages=72β103|doi=10.1016/0022-2496(67)90042-9|hdl=2027.42/33365|hdl-access=free}}</ref> <ref name="SlovicLichtenstein1968">{{cite journal|last1=Slovic|first1=Paul|last2=Lichtenstein|first2=Sarah|title=Relative importance of probabilities and payoffs in risk taking|journal=Journal of Experimental Psychology|volume=78|issue=3, Pt.2|year=1968|pages=1β18|doi=10.1037/h0026468}}</ref> <ref name="Hoffman">{{cite journal|author=Hoffman, Elizabeth|author2=Spitzer, Matthew L.|year=1993|title=Willingness to Pay vs. Willingness to Accept: Legal and Economic Implications|volume=71|journal= Washington University Law Quarterly|pages=59β114|url=http://openscholarship.wustl.edu/law_lawreview/vol71/iss1/2/|issn=0043-0862}}</ref> <ref name="KahnemanTversky1979">{{cite journal|last1=Kahneman|first1=Daniel|last2=Tversky|first2=Amos|title=Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk|journal=Econometrica|volume=47|issue=2|year=1979|pages=263|doi=10.2307/1914185|jstor=1914185|citeseerx=10.1.1.407.1910}}</ref> <ref name="Morewedge2009">{{cite journal|last1=Morewedge|first1=Carey K.|last2=Shu|first2=Lisa L.|last3=Gilbert|first3=Daniel T.|last4=Wilson|first4=Timothy D.|title=Bad riddance or good rubbish? Ownership and not loss aversion causes the endowment effect|journal=Journal of Experimental Social Psychology|volume=45|issue=4|year=2009|pages=947β951|doi=10.1016/j.jesp.2009.05.014}}</ref> <ref name="Maddux">{{cite journal |last1=Maddux |first1=William W. |last2=Yang |first2=Haiyang |last3=Falk |first3=Carl |last4=Adam |first4=Hajo |last5=Adair |first5=Wendy |last6=Endo |first6=Yumi |last7=Carmon |first7=Ziv |last8=Heine |first8=Steve J. |title=For Whom Is Parting With Possessions More Painful?: Cultural Differences in the Endowment Effect|journal=Psychological Science |volume=21 |issue=12 |year=2010 |pages=1910β1917 |doi=10.1177/0956797610388818|pmid=21097722|s2cid=16860986}}</ref> <ref name="Harless">{{cite journal|last1=Harless |first1=David W.|title=More laboratory evidence on the disparity between willingness to pay and compensation demanded|journal=Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization|volume=11|issue=3 |year=1989|pages=359β379|doi=10.1016/0167-2681(89)90035-8}}</ref> <ref name="Knez">{{cite journal|last1=Knez|first1=Peter |last2=Smith|first2=Vernon L.|last3=Williams |first3=Arlington W. |title=Individual Rationality, Market Rationality, and Value Estimation|journal=American Economic Review|date=1985|volume=75 |issue=2|pages=397β402|jstor=1805632}}</ref> <ref name="Hovenkamp">{{cite journal|last1=Hovenkamp |first1=Herbert|title=Legal Policy and the Endowment Effect|journal=The Journal of Legal Studies|volume=20|issue=2|year=1991|pages=225β247|doi=10.1086/467886|s2cid=155051169}}</ref> <ref name="Fischel">{{cite journal |last1=Fischel |first1=William A. |title=The offer/ask disparity and just compensation for takings: A constitutional choice perspective |journal=International Review of Law and Economics |volume=15 |issue=2 |year=1995 |pages=187β203 |doi=10.1016/0144-8188(94)00005-F|doi-access=free }}</ref> <ref name="Carrots">{{cite journal |title=Carrots dressed as sticks |date=14 January 2010 |journal=Economist |volume=394 |issue=8665 |page=72 |url=http://www.economist.com/node/15271260}} Cites: {{cite journal |last1=Hossain |first1=Tanjim |last2=List |first2=John A. |title=The Behavioralist Visits the Factory: Increasing Productivity Using Simple Framing Manipulations |journal=Management Science |volume=58 |issue=12 |year=2012 |pages=2151β2167 |doi=10.1287/mnsc.1120.1544 |url=http://s3.amazonaws.com/fieldexperiments-papers2/papers/00468.pdf}}</ref> <ref name="Huck">{{cite journal|last1=Huck|first1=Steffen |last2=Kirchsteiger|first2=Georg|last3=Oechssler|first3=JΓΆrg |title=Learning to like what you have β explaining the endowment effect|journal=The Economic Journal|volume=115 |issue=505 |year=2005|pages=689β702 |doi=10.1111/j.1468-0297.2005.01015.x|hdl=10419/22833|s2cid=16245289 |url=https://dipot.ulb.ac.be/dspace/bitstream/2013/149578/3/2005EJ-EndowmentEffect.pdf|hdl-access=free}}</ref> <ref name="Kanngiesser">{{cite journal |last1=Kanngiesser |first1=Patricia |last2=Santos |first2=Laurie R. |last3=Hood |first3=Bruce M. |last4=Call |first4=Josep |title=The limits of endowment effects in great apes (Pan paniscus, Pan troglodytes, Gorilla gorilla, Pongo pygmaeus) |journal=Journal of Comparative Psychology |volume=125 |issue=4 |year=2011 |pages=436β445 |doi=10.1037/a0024516|pmid=21767009}}</ref> <ref name="KKT91">{{cite journal |last1=Kahneman |first1=Daniel |last2=Knetsch |first2=Jack L. |last3=Thaler |first3=Richard H. |title=Anomalies: The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias |journal=The Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=5 |issue=1 |year=1991 |pages=193β206 |doi=10.1257/jep.5.1.193 |doi-access=free}}</ref> }} ==External links== * {{cite journal |last1=Plott |first1=Charles R. |last2=Zeiler |first2=Kathryn |author-link2=Kathryn Zeiler |title=The Willingness to PayβWillingness to Accept Gap, the 'Endowment Effect,' Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations |journal=American Economic Review |volume=95 |issue=3 |date=June 2005 |pages=530β545 |ssrn=615861 |doi=10.1257/0002828054201387 |doi-access=free |url=https://resolver.caltech.edu/CaltechAUTHORS:PLOaer05}} * {{cite journal |last1=Plott |first1=Charles R. |last2=Zeiler |first2=Kathryn |author-link2=Kathryn Zeiler |title=Exchange Asymmetries Incorrectly Interpreted as Evidence of Endowment Effect Theory and Prospect Theory?|journal=American Economic Review |volume=97 |issue=4 |year=2007 |pages=1449β1466 |ssrn=940633 |doi=10.1257/aer.97.4.1449 |s2cid=16803164 |url=https://authors.library.caltech.edu/9202/1/PLOaer07.pdf}} * Wright, Josh (2005). [https://web.archive.org/web/20051206012614/http://busmovie.typepad.com/ideoblog/2005/12/the_endowment_e.html The Endowment Effect's Disappearing Act], and (2009) [https://web.archive.org/web/20091010001411/http://www.truthonthemarket.com/2009/10/06/whats-wrong-with-the-endowment-effect/ What's Wrong With the Endowment Effect?] * [http://mises.org/daily/5839/The-Mystery-of-the-Endowment-Effect The "Mystery" of the Endowment Effect], Per Bylund, December 28, 2011 * [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2862021 What Explains Observed Reluctance to Trade? A Comprehensive Literature Review] [[Category:Cognitive biases]] [[Category:Behavioral finance]] [[Category:Prospect theory]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Blockquote
(
edit
)
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite news
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Portal
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)