Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Market failure
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|When markets do not produce goods or services as efficiently as possible}} [[File:Godorf Cologne Rhineland-Refinery-Cooling-Towers-during-demolition-02.jpg|thumb|right|200px|While factories and refineries provide jobs and wages, they are also an example of a market failure, as they impose [[negative externalities]] on the surrounding region via their [[air pollution|airborne pollutants]].]] In [[neoclassical economics]], '''market failure''' is a situation in which the allocation of [[goods and services]] by a [[free market]] is not [[Pareto efficient]], often leading to a net loss of [[economic value]].<ref>{{Cite web|last=NSW Government|date=2017|title=A guide to categorising market failures for government policy development and evaluation|url=https://media.opengov.nsw.gov.au/pairtree_root/41/eb/7e/1a/65/1b/4e/a2/b8/d8/68/9a/1d/8d/75/1a/obj/PUB17_509_Market__failure_guide.pdf|website=New South Wales Department of Industry}}</ref><ref>John O. Ledyard (2008). Market Failure, ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics''</ref><ref name="krugman">[[Paul Krugman]] and [[Robin Wells Krugman|Robin Wells]] (2006). ''Economics'', New York, Worth Publishers.</ref> The first known use of the term by economists was in 1958,<ref name="Bator">[[Francis M. Bator]] (1958). "The Anatomy of Market Failure," ''Quarterly Journal of Economics'', 72(3) pp. [http://instruct1.cit.cornell.edu/Courses/econ335/out/bator_qje.pdf 351–379] (press '''+'''). </ref> but the concept has been traced back to the Victorian writers [[John Stuart Mill]] and [[Henry Sidgwick]].<ref>[[JS Mill]], ''Principles of Political Economy]]'' (1848) Book V, chapter IX, on exceptions to laissez faire</ref><ref name="Medema">Steven G. Medema (2007). "The Hesitant Hand: Mill, Sidgwick, and the Evolution of the Theory of Market Failure," ''History of Political Economy'', 39(3), [http://hope.dukejournals.org/cgi/pdf_extract/39/3/331 pp. 331]–358. 2004 [http://www.utilitarian.net/sidgwick/about/2004070102.pdf Online Working Paper.] {{Webarchive|url=https://web.archive.org/web/20070927021943/http://www.utilitarian.net/sidgwick/about/2004070102.pdf |date=2007-09-27 }}</ref> Market failures are often associated with [[public goods]],<ref>[[Joseph E. Stiglitz]] (1989). "Markets, Market Failures, and Development," ''American Economic Review'', 79(2), pp. [https://www.jstor.org/stable/1827756 197–203.]</ref> [[time-inconsistent preferences]],<ref>•Ignacio Palacios-Huerta (2003) "Time-inconsistent preferences in Adam Smith and David Hume," ''[[History of Political Economy]]'', 35(2), pp. 241–268 [http://www.palacios-huerta.com/docs/hopefinal.pdf]</ref> [[Information asymmetry|information asymmetries]],<ref>• Charles Wilson (2008). "adverse selection," ''The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics'' 2nd Edition. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_A000040&edition=&field=keyword&q=asymmetric%20information&topicid=&result_number=7 Abstract.]<br /> • [[Joseph E. Stiglitz]] (1998). "The Private Uses of Public Interests: Incentives and Institutions," ''Journal of Economic Perspectives'', 12(2), pp. [https://www.aeaweb.org/articles?id=10.1257/jep.12.2.3 3–22.]</ref> [[Market structure|failures of competition]], [[principal–agent problem]]s, [[externalities]],<ref name= "Laffont">[[Jean-Jacques Laffont|J.J. Laffont]] (2008). "externalities," ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'', 2nd Ed. [http://www.dictionaryofeconomics.com/article?id=pde2008_E000200&q=externality&topicid=&result_number=9 Abstract.]</ref> [[unequal bargaining power]],<ref>[[Adam Smith]], ''The Wealth of Nations]]'' (1776) Book I, chapter 8. [[Thomas Piketty]], ''[[Capital in the Twenty-First Century]]'' (2011) ch 9, ‘insofar as employers have more bargaining power than workers and the conditions of “pure and perfect” competition that one finds in the simplest economic models fail to be satisfied…’. Discussed in E McGaughey, ‘Behavioural Economics and Labour Law’ (2014) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2460685 LSE Law, Society and Economy Working Papers 20/2014], 12-14 in A Ludlow and A Blackham, New Frontiers in Empirical Labour Law Research (2015) ch 6</ref> behavioral irrationality (in [[behavioral economics]]),<ref>e.g. D Kahneman, ''[[Thinking, Fast and Slow]]'' (2011)</ref> and macro-economic failures (such as unemployment and inflation).<ref>J Stiglitz and J Rosengard, ''The Economics of the Public Sector'' (2015) ch 4</ref> The neoclassical school attributes market failures to the interference of [[self-regulatory organization]]s, governments or supra-national institutions in a particular [[Market (economics)|market]], although this view is criticized by heterodox economists.<ref>[[Kenneth J. Arrow]] (1969). "The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Market versus Non-market Allocations," in ''Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPP System'', Washington, D.C., Joint Economic Committee of Congress. PDF reprint as pp. [http://www.econ.ucsb.edu/~tedb/Courses/UCSBpf/readings/ArrowNonMktActivity1969.pdf 1–16] (press '''+''').</ref><ref name="rees">{{cite book |last=Gravelle |first=Hugh |author2=Ray Rees |title=Microeconomics |publisher=Prentice Hall, Financial Times |year=2004 |location=Essex, England |pages=314–346}}</ref> Economists, especially [[microeconomics|microeconomists]], are often concerned with the causes of market failure and possible means of correction.<ref name="mankiw">{{cite book |last=Mankiw |first=Gregory |author2=Ronald Kneebone |author3=Kenneth McKenzie |author4=Nicholas Row |title=Principles of Microeconomics: Second Canadian Edition |publisher=Thomson-Nelson |year=2002 |location=United States |pages=157–158 }}</ref> Such analysis plays an important role in many types of [[Public policy (law)|public policy]] decisions and studies. However, government policy interventions, such as [[tax]]es, [[Subsidy|subsidies]], [[Incomes policy|wage]] and [[price controls]], and [[regulation]]s, may also lead to an inefficient allocation of resources, sometimes called [[government failure]].<ref name="weimervining">{{cite book |last=Weimer |first=David |author2=Aidan R. Vining |title=Policy Analysis: Concepts and Practice |url=https://archive.org/details/policyanalysisco0000weim_u3o9 |url-access=registration |publisher=Prentice Hall |year=2004 |isbn=9780131830011}}</ref> Most mainstream economists believe that there are circumstances (like [[building code]]s, [[fire safety]] regulations or [[endangered species]] laws) in which it is possible for government or other organizations to improve the inefficient market outcome. Several [[heterodox economics|heterodox]] schools of thought disagree with this as a matter of ideology.<ref name="n. gregory mankiw">{{cite book |last=Mankiw |first=N. Gregory |author-link=N. Gregory Mankiw |title=Brief Principles of Macroeconomics |publisher=South-Western Cengage Learning |year=2009 |pages=10–12}}</ref><ref>{{cite web | url=https://blogs.law.ox.ac.uk/housing-after-grenfell/blog/2020/01/reflecting-systemic-failures-illustrated-fire-safety-crisis | title=Reflecting on the systemic failures illustrated by the fire-safety crisis in blocks of flats | Oxford Law Blogs | date=15 January 2020 }}</ref> An ''ecological'' market failure exists when human activity in a market economy is exhausting critical [[non-renewable resource]]s, disrupting fragile ecosystems, or [[Pollution|overloading]] biospheric waste absorption capacities. In none of these cases does the criterion of Pareto efficiency obtain.<ref name=hd03 /> ==Categories== Different economists have different views about what events are the sources of market failure. Mainstream economic analysis widely accepts that a market failure in relation to several causes.<ref>J Stiglitz and J Rosengard, Economics of the Public Sector (4th edn 2015) chapter 4, 83-94. T Piketty, ''Capital in the Twenty-First Century (2011) ch 9. D Kahneman, ''Thinking, Fast and Slow'' (2011)</ref> These include if the market is "[[monopolised]]" or a small group of businesses hold significant [[market power]] resulting in a "failure of competition"; if production of the good or service results in an [[externality]] (external costs or benefits); if the good or service is a "[[Public good (economics)|public good]]"; if there is a "failure of information" or [[information asymmetry]]; if there is [[unequal bargaining power]]; if there is bounded rationality or irrationality; and if there are macro-economic failures such as unemployment or inflation. ===Failure of competition=== {{main|Market structure|market power|}} [[Agent (economics)|Agent]]s in a market can gain [[market power]], allowing them to block other mutually beneficial [[gains from trade]] from occurring. This can lead to inefficiency due to [[imperfect competition]], which can take many different forms, such as [[Monopoly|monopolies]],<ref name="demartino01">{{cite book |title=Global Economy, Global Justice |last=DeMartino |first=George |year=2000 |publisher=Routledge |isbn=0415224012 |page=70 |url=https://books.google.com/books?id=bh66WFcdT9sC}}</ref> [[monopsonies]], or [[monopolistic competition]], if the agent does not implement perfect price discrimination. [[File:NIGU transmision line near Te Kauwhata.JPG|thumb|270px|In small countries like [[New Zealand]], [[electricity transmission]] is a natural monopoly. Due to enormous [[fixed cost]]s and small [[Market (economics)|market size]], one seller can serve the entire market at the downward-sloping section of its [[Cost curve#Short-run average total cost curve (SRATC or SRAC)|average cost curve]], meaning that it will have lower average costs than any potential entrant.]] It is then a further question about what circumstances allow a monopoly to arise. In some cases, monopolies can maintain themselves where there are "[[barriers to entry]]" that prevent other companies from effectively entering and competing in an industry or market. Or there could exist significant [[first-mover advantage]]s in the market that make it difficult for other firms to compete. Moreover, monopoly can be a result of geographical conditions created by huge distances or isolated locations. This leads to a situation where there are only few communities scattered across a vast territory with only one supplier. Australia is an example that meets this description.<ref name=":0">{{Cite book|title=The political economy of local government|last=Brian.|first=Dollery|date=2001|publisher=Edward Elgar Pub|others=Wallis, Joe (Joe L.)|isbn=1840644516|location=Northampton, MA|oclc=46462759}}</ref> A [[natural monopoly]] is a firm whose per-unit cost decreases as it increases output; in this situation it is most efficient (from a cost perspective) to have only a single producer of a good. Natural monopolies display so-called increasing returns to scale. It means that at all possible outputs [[marginal cost]] needs to be below average cost if average cost is declining. One of the reasons is the existence of fixed costs, which must be paid without considering the amount of output, what results in a state where costs are evenly divided over more units leading to the reduction of cost per unit.<ref>{{Cite web|url=http://www.economicsonline.co.uk/Business_economics/Natural_monopolies.html|title=Natural monopolies exist when one firm dominates an industry|website=www.economicsonline.co.uk|access-date=2018-04-24}}</ref> ===Public goods=== Some markets can fail due to the nature of the goods being exchanged. For instance, some goods can display the attributes of [[public goods]]<ref name="demartino01" /> or [[common good]]s,<ref>{{Citation|last=Hussain|first=Waheed|title=The Common Good|date=2018|url=https://plato.stanford.edu/archives/spr2018/entries/common-good/|encyclopedia=The Stanford Encyclopedia of Philosophy|editor-last=Zalta|editor-first=Edward N.|edition=Spring 2018|publisher=Metaphysics Research Lab, Stanford University|access-date=2020-10-31}}</ref> wherein sellers are unable to [[Excludability|exclude]] non-buyers from using a product, as in the development of inventions that may spread freely once revealed, such as developing a new method of harvesting. This can cause underinvestment because developers cannot capture enough of the benefits from success to make the development effort worthwhile. This can also lead to [[resource depletion]] in the case of [[common-pool resource]]s, whereby the use of the resource is [[Competition|rival]] but [[Excludability|non-excludable]], there is no incentive for users to conserve the resource. An example of this is a lake with a natural supply of fish: if people catch the fish faster than the fish can reproduce, then the fish population will dwindle until there are no fish left for [[future generations]]. ===Externalities=== A good or service could also have significant [[Externality|externalities]],<ref name="Laffont" /><ref name="demartino01" /> where gains or losses associated with the product, production or consumption of a product, differ from the private [[cost]]. These gains or losses are imposed on a third-party that did not take part in the original market transaction. These externalities can be innate to the methods of production or other conditions important to the market.<ref name="krugman" /> "The Problem of Social Cost" illuminates a different path towards social optimum showing the [[Pigouvian tax]] is not the only way towards solving externalities. It is hard to say who discovered externalities first since many classical economists saw the importance of education or a lighthouse, but it was Alfred Marshall who wanted to explore this more. He wondered why long-run supply curve under perfect competition could be decreasing so he founded "external economies" (<ref>Sandmo 228</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Sandmo |first1=Agnar |title=Economics evolving : a history of economic thought |date=2011 |publisher=Princeton University Press |location=Princeton, N.J. |isbn=9780691148427 |pages=228 }}228</ref>). Externalities can be positive or negative depending on how a good/service is produced or what the good/service provides to the public. Positive externalities tend to be goods like vaccines, schools, or advancement of technology. They usually provide the public with a positive gain. Negative externalities would be like noise or air pollution. Coase shows this with his example of the case ''Sturges v. Bridgman'' involving a confectioner and doctor. The confectioner had lived there many years and soon the doctor several years into residency decides to build a consulting room; it is right by the confectioner's kitchen which releases vibrations from his grinding of pestle and mortar (<ref>The Problem of Social Cost 8</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Coase |first1=Ronald |title=The Problem of Social Cost |date=1960 |publisher=The University of Chicago Press |location=Chicago |isbn=9781539433408 |pages=8 }}</ref> ). The doctor wins the case by a claim of nuisance so the confectioner would have to cease from using his machine. Coase argues there could have been bargains instead the confectioner could have paid the doctor to continue the source of income from using the machine hopefully it is more than what the Doctor is losing (<ref>The Problem of Social Cost 9</ref><ref>{{cite book |last1=Coase |first1=Ronald |title=The Problem of Social Cost |date=1960 |publisher=The University of Chicago Press |location=Chicago |isbn=9781539433408 |pages=9 }}</ref> ). Vice versa the doctor could have paid the confectioner to cease production since he is prohibiting a source of income from the confectioner. Coase used a few more examples similar in scope dealing with social cost of an externality and the possible resolutions. [[File:6th Avenue from 49th.jpg|thumb|300px|Congested [[Avenue of the Americas]] in [[Midtown Manhattan|Midtown]] [[Manhattan]], [[New York City]], which leads the world in urban automobile traffic congestion,<ref name=NYCCongestion>{{cite web|url=https://www.economist.com/united-states/2024/11/21/congestion-pricing-in-new-york-gets-the-go-ahead-after-all-maybe|title=Congestion pricing in New York gets the go-ahead after all. Maybe|publisher=The Economist|date=November 21, 2024|access-date=November 21, 2024|quote=But traffic is bad most days, with more than 900,000 cars entering Manhattan’s central business district. INRIX, a traffic-data firm, found that New York City leads the world in urban traffic congestion among the cities scored, with the average driver stationary for 101 hours a year.}}</ref> but which has implemented [[Congestion pricing in New York City|congestion pricing]] in January 2025 to address the gridlock]] [[Traffic congestion]] is an example of market failure that incorporates both non-excludability and externality. Public roads are common resources that are available for the entire population's use (non-excludable), and act as a [[Complementary good|complement]] to cars (the more roads there are, the more useful cars become). Because there is very low cost but high benefit to individual drivers in using the roads, the roads become congested, decreasing their usefulness to society. Furthermore, driving can impose [[hidden costs]] on society through pollution (externality). Solutions for this include [[public transport]]ation, [[congestion pricing]], tolls, and other ways of making the driver include the [[social cost]] in the decision to drive.<ref name="krugman" /> Perhaps the best example of the inefficiency associated with common/public goods and externalities is the environmental harm caused by [[pollution]] and [[overexploitation]] of [[natural resource]]s.<ref name="krugman" /> ====Coase theorem==== The [[Coase theorem]], developed by [[Ronald Coase]] and labeled as such by George Stigler, states that private transactions are efficient as long as property rights exist, only a small number of parties are involved, and transactions costs are low. Additionally, this efficiency will take place regardless of who owns the property rights. This theory comes from a section of Coase's Nobel prize-winning work ''[[The Problem of Social Cost]]''. While the assumptions of low transactions costs and a small number of parties involved may not always be applicable in real-world markets, Coase's work changed the long-held belief that the owner of [[property rights]] was a major determining factor in whether or not a market would fail.<ref>Michael Parkin (2008). ''Microeconomics'', 9th Ed. p. 379. University of Western Ontario.</ref> The Coase theorem points out when one would expect the market to function properly even when there are externalities. <blockquote>A market is an institution in which individuals or firms exchange not just commodities, but the ''rights'' to use them in particular ways for particular amounts of time. [...] Markets are institutions which organize the ''exchange of control'' of commodities, where the nature of the control is defined by the property rights attached to the commodities.<ref name="rees"/></blockquote> As a result, agents' control over the uses of their goods and services can be imperfect, because the system of rights which defines that control is incomplete. Typically, this falls into two generalized rights – ''excludability'' and ''transferability''. Excludability deals with the ability of agents to control who uses their commodity, and for how long – and the related costs associated with doing so. Transferability reflects the right of agents to transfer the rights of use from one agent to another, for instance by selling or [[leasing]] a commodity, and the costs associated with doing so. If a given system of rights does not fully guarantee these at minimal (or no) cost, then the resulting distribution can be inefficient.<ref name="rees"/> Considerations such as these form an important part of the work of [[institutional economics]].<ref name="bowles">{{cite book | last = Bowles | first = Samuel | title = Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution | publisher = Russel Sage Foundation | year = 2004 | location = United States}}</ref> Nonetheless, views still differ on whether something displaying these attributes is meaningful without the information provided by the market price system.<ref>Machan, R. Tibor, [http://media.hoover.org/documents/0817929428_xi.pdf ''Some Skeptical Reflections on Research and Development''], Hoover Press</ref> ===Information failures=== [[Information asymmetry|informational asymmetry]] is considered a leading type of market failure.<ref>J Stigitz and J Rosengard, ''Economics of the Public Sector'' (2015) ch 4, 87-93</ref><ref name="krugman"/><ref name="demartino01" /> This is where there is an imbalance of information between two or more parties to a transaction. One example is [[incomplete markets]], for example where second hand car buyers know there is a risk a car may break down, and systematically under-pay to discount this risk: this leads to fewer cars being sold overall; or where insurers know that some policyholders will withhold information, and systematically refuse to insure certain groups because of this risk. This may result in economic inefficiency, but also have a possibility of improving efficiency through market, legal, and regulatory remedies. From [[contract theory]], decisions in transactions where one party has more or better [[information]] than the other is considered "asymmetry". This creates an imbalance of power in transactions which can sometimes cause the transactions to go awry. Examples of this problem are [[adverse selection]]<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Finkelstein|first1=Amy|last2=Poterba|first2=James|date=2004|title=Adverse Selection in Insurance Markets: Policyholder Evidence from the U.K. Annuity Market|url=http://papers.nber.org/papers/w8045.pdf|journal=Journal of Political Economy|volume=112|issue=1|pages=183–208|doi=10.1086/379936|jstor=10.1086/379936|s2cid=14608232 }}</ref> and [[moral hazard]]. Most commonly, information asymmetries are studied in the context of [[principal–agent problem]]s. [[George Akerlof]], [[Michael Spence]], and [[Joseph E. Stiglitz]] developed the idea and shared the 2001 Nobel Prize in Economics.<ref>{{cite journal|last=Huffman |first=Max|title=Neo-Behavioralism?|date=December 2010|page=9|ssrn=1730365}}</ref> ===Unequal bargaining power=== {{main|Inequality of bargaining power}} In ''The Wealth of Nations'' [[Adam Smith]] explored how an employer had the ability to "hold out" longer in a dispute over pay with workers because workers were more likely to go hungry more quickly, given that the employer has more property, and have fewer obstacles in organising.<ref>A Smith, ''The Wealth of Nations'' (1776) Book I, chapter 2</ref> Unequal bargaining power has been used as a concept justifying economic regulation, particularly for employment, consumer, and tenancy rights since the early 20th century.<ref>e.g. EU [[National Labor Relations Act of 1935]] §1. EU [[Unfair Terms in Consumer Contracts Directive]].</ref> [[Thomas Piketty]] in ''[[Capital in the Twenty-First Century]]'' explains how unequal bargaining power undermines "conditions of "pure and perfect" competition" and leads to a persistently lower share of income for labor, and leads to growing inequality.<ref>T Piketty, ''[[Capital in the Twenty-First Century]]'' (2011) ch 9, ‘insofar as employers have more bargaining power than workers and the conditions of “pure and perfect” competition that one finds in the simplest economic models fail to be satisfied…’.</ref> While it was argued by [[Ronald Coase]] that bargaining power merely affects distribution of income, but not productive efficiency, the modern behavioural evidence establishes that distribution or fairness of exchance does affect motivation to work,<ref>A Cohn, E Fehr, B Herrmann and F Schneider, ‘Social Comparison in the Workplace: Evidence from a Field Experiment’ (2014) Journal of the European Economic Association</ref> and therefore unequal bargaining power is a market failure.<ref>Discussed in E McGaughey, ‘Behavioural Economics and Labour Law’ (2014) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2460685 LSE Law, Society and Economy Working Papers 20/2014], 12-13 in A Ludlow and A Blackham, New Frontiers in Empirical Labour Law Research (2015) ch 6</ref> Notably, the price of labour was excluded from the scope of the original charts on supply and demand by their inventor, [[Fleeming Jenkin]], who considered that the wages of labour could not be equated with ordinary markets for commodities such as corn, because of labour's unequal bargaining power.<ref>F Jenkin, 'The Graphic Representation of the Laws of Supply and Demand and Other Essays on Political Economy' (1887, 1996 edn Routledge)</ref> ===Bounded rationality=== {{main|Bounded rationality|Behavioral economics}} In ''Models of Man'', [[Herbert A. Simon]] points out that most people are only partly [[Rationality|rational]], and are emotional/[[irrational]] in the remaining part of their actions. In another work, he states "boundedly rational agents experience limits in formulating and solving complex problems and in processing (receiving, storing, retrieving, transmitting) [[information]]" ([[Oliver E. Williamson|Williamson]], p. 553, citing Simon). Simon describes a number of dimensions along which "classical" models of rationality can be made somewhat more realistic, while sticking within the vein of fairly rigorous formalization. These include: * limiting what sorts of [[utility]] functions there might be. * recognizing the costs of gathering and processing information. * the possibility of having a "[[vector (geometry)|vector]]" or "multi-valued" utility function. Simon suggests that economic agents employ the use of [[heuristics]] to make decisions rather than a strict rigid rule of optimization. They do this because of the complexity of the situation, and their inability to process and compute the expected utility of every alternative action. Deliberation costs might be high and there are often other, concurrent economic activities also requiring decisions. The concept of bounded rationality was significantly expanded through behavioral economics research, suggesting that people are systematically irrational in day to day decisions. [[Daniel Kahneman]] in ''[[Thinking, Fast and Slow]]'' explored how human beings operate as if they have two systems of thinking: a fast "system 1" mode of thought for snap, everyday decisions which applies rules of thumb but is frequently mistaken; and a slow "system 2" mode of thought that is careful and deliberative, but not as often used in making ordinary decisions to buy and sell or do business. ===Macro-economic failures=== {{main|Unemployment|Inflation|Macroeconomics}} "Unemployment, inflation and "disequilibrium" are considered a category of market failure at a "macro economic" or "whole economy" level.<ref>J Stiglitz and J Rosengard, ''The Economics of the Public Sector'' (2015) ch 4, 93</ref> These symptoms (of high job loss, or fast rising prices or both) can result from a financial crash, a recession or depression, and the market failure is evident in the sustained underproduction of an economy, or a tendency not to recover immediately. Macroeconomic [[business cycle]]s are a part of the market. They are characterized by constant downswings and upswings which influence economic activity. Therefore, this situation requires some kind of government intervention.<ref name=":0" /> ===Persistent labor shortages=== {{main|Shortage#Labour shortage||}} Widespread and persistent domestic labour shortages in various countries are examples of market failure, whereby excessively low [[Salary|salaries]] (relative to the domestic [[cost of living]]) and adverse [[Occupational stress#Causes of occupational stress|working conditions]] (excessive [[workload]] and [[Working time|working hours]]) in low-wage industries ([[Hospitality industry|hospitality and leisure]], [[Educational stage|education]], [[health care]], [[Rail transport|rail transportation]], [[Warehouse|warehousing]], [[aviation]], [[retail]], [[manufacturing]], [[Food industry|food]], [[construction]], [[elderly care]]), collectively lead to [[occupational burnout]] and attrition of existing workers, insufficient [[Incentive|incentives]] to attract the inflow supply of domestic workers, short-staffing and regular [[shift work]] at [[Workplace|workplaces]] and further exacerbation ([[positive feedback]]) of staff shortages. Poor job quality and artificial shortages perpetuated by salary-paying employers, deter workers from entering or remaining in these roles. Labour shortages occur broadly across multiple industries within a rapidly expanding economy, whilst labour shortages often occur within specific industries (which generally offer low salaries) even during economic periods of high unemployment. In response to domestic labour shortages, business associations such as [[Chamber of commerce|chambers of commerce]], [[Trade association|trade associations]] or [[Employers' organization|employers' organizations]] would generally lobby to governments for an increase of the inward [[immigration]] of [[Foreign worker|foreign workers]] from countries which are [[Developing country|less developed]] and have lower salaries. In addition, business associations have campaigned for greater state provision of [[child care]], which would enable more women to re-enter the labour workforce at a lower wage rate to achieve [[economic equilibrium]]. However, as labour shortages in the relevant low-wage industries are often widespread globally throughout many countries in the world, immigration would only partially address the chronic labour shortages in the relevant low-wage industries in [[Developed country|developed countries]] (whilst simultaneously discouraging local labour from entering the relevant industries) and in turn cause greater labour shortages in developing countries. ==Interpretations and policy examples== The above causes represent the [[mainstream economics|mainstream]] view of what market failures mean and of their importance in the economy. This analysis follows the lead of the [[Neoclassical economics|neoclassical]] school, and relies on the notion of [[Pareto efficiency]],<ref name="mises">{{cite web | last = MacKenzie | first = D.W. | title = The Market Failure Myth |publisher=[[Ludwig von Mises Institute]] | date = 2002-08-26 | url = https://mises.org/library/market-failure-myth | access-date = 2008-11-25 }}</ref> which can be in the "[[public interest]]", as well as in interests of stakeholders with [[Equity (economics)|equity]].<ref name="mankiw"/> This form of analysis has also been adopted by the [[Keynesian]] or [[new Keynesian economics|new Keynesian]] schools in modern [[macroeconomics]], applying it to [[Léon Walras|Walras]]ian models of [[general equilibrium]] in order to deal with failures to attain [[full employment]], or the non-adjustment of prices and wages. Policies to prevent market failure are already commonly implemented in the economy. For example, to prevent information asymmetry, members of the New York Stock Exchange agree to abide by its rules in order to promote a fair and orderly market in the trading of listed securities. The members of the [[NYSE]] presumably believe that each member is individually better off if every member adheres to its rules – even if they have to forego money-making opportunities that would violate those rules. A simple example of policies to address market power is government antitrust policies. As an additional example of externalities, municipal governments enforce building codes and license tradesmen to mitigate the incentive to use cheaper (but more dangerous) construction practices, ensuring that the total cost of new construction includes the (otherwise external) cost of preventing future tragedies. The voters who elect municipal officials presumably feel that they are individually better off if everyone complies with the local codes, even if those codes may increase the cost of construction in their communities. [[CITES]] is an international treaty to protect the world's common interest in preserving endangered species – a classic "public good" – against the private interests of poachers, developers and other market participants who might otherwise reap monetary benefits without bearing the known and unknown costs that extinction could create. Even without knowing the true cost of extinction, the signatory countries believe that the societal costs far outweigh the possible private gains that they have agreed to forego. Some remedies for market failure can resemble other market failures. For example, the issue of systematic underinvestment in research is addressed by the [[patent]] system that creates artificial monopolies for successful inventions. ==Objections== {{See also|Government failure|||}} ===Public choice=== Economists such as [[Milton Friedman]] from the [[Chicago School of Economics|Chicago school]] and others from the [[Public choice theory|Public Choice]] school, argue{{citation needed|date=August 2015}} that market failure does not necessarily imply that the government should attempt to solve market failures, because the costs of [[government failure]] might be worse than those of the market failure it attempts to fix. This failure of government is seen as the result of the inherent problems of democracy and other forms of government perceived by this school and also of the power of special-interest groups ([[rent-seeking|rent seekers]]) both in the [[private sector]] and in the government [[bureaucracy]]. Conditions that many would regard as negative are often seen as an effect of subversion of the free market by [[coercion|coercive]] government intervention. Beyond philosophical objections, a further issue is the practical difficulty that any single decision maker may face in trying to understand (and perhaps predict) the numerous interactions that occur between producers and consumers in any market. ===Austrian=== Some advocates of ''[[laissez-faire]]'' [[capitalism]], including many economists of the [[Austrian School]], argue that there is no such phenomenon as "market failure". [[Israel Kirzner]] states that, "Efficiency for a social system means the efficiency with which it permits its individual members to achieve their individual goals."<ref>{{cite book|author=Israel Kirzner|title=Market Theory and the Price System|url=https://archive.org/details/markettheorypric00kirz|url-access=limited|year=1963|publisher=D. Van Nostrand Company|location=Princeton. N.J.|page=[https://archive.org/details/markettheorypric00kirz/page/n46 35]|author-link=Israel Kirzner}}</ref> Inefficiency only arises when means are chosen by individuals that are inconsistent with their desired goals.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Roy E. Cordato|title=The Austrian Theory of Efficiency and the Role of Government|year=1980|journal=[[The Journal of Libertarian Studies]] |url=https://www.mises.org/journals/jls/4_4/4_4_6.pdf|volume=4|issue=4|pages=393–403 [396]}}</ref> This definition of efficiency differs from that of [[Pareto efficiency]], and forms the basis of the theoretical argument against the existence of market failures. However, providing that the conditions of the [[first welfare theorem]] are met, these two definitions agree, and give identical results. Austrians argue that the market tends to eliminate its inefficiencies through the process of [[entrepreneurship]] driven by the [[profit motive]]; something the government has great difficulty detecting, or correcting.<ref>{{cite journal|author=Roy E. Cordato|title=The Austrian Theory of Efficiency and the Role of Government|year=1980|journal=The Journal of Libertarian Studies|url=https://www.mises.org/journals/jls/4_4/4_4_6.pdf|volume=4|issue=4|pages=393–403}}</ref> ===Marxian=== Objections also exist on more fundamental bases, such as [[Marxian economics|Marxian analysis]]. Colloquial uses of the term "market failure" reflect the notion of a market "failing" to provide some desired attribute different from efficiency – for instance, high levels of inequality can be considered a "market failure", yet are not [[Pareto efficiency|Pareto inefficient]], and so would not be considered a market failure by mainstream economics.<ref name="krugman"/> In addition, many [[Marxian economics|Marxian]] economists would argue that the system of private property rights is a fundamental problem in itself, and that resources should be allocated in another way entirely. This is different from concepts of "market failure" which focuses on specific situations – typically seen as "abnormal" – where markets have inefficient outcomes. Marxists, in contrast, would say that markets have inefficient and democratically unwanted outcomes – viewing market failure as an inherent feature of any capitalist economy – and typically omit it from discussion, preferring to ration finite goods not exclusively through a price mechanism, but based upon need as determined by society expressed through the community. === Ecological === {{Ecological economics|Concepts}} {{See also|Ecological economics #Not 'externalities', but cost shifting| Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen #Criticising neoclassical economics (weak versus strong sustainability)|Tragedy of the commons|Uneconomic growth}} In [[ecological economics]], the concept of [[Externality|externalities]] is considered a misnomer, since market agents are viewed as making their incomes and profits by [[Ecological economics#Not 'externalities', but cost shifting|systematically 'shifting' the social and ecological costs]] of their activities onto other agents, including future generations. Hence, externalities is a ''modus operandi'' of the market, not a failure: The market cannot exist without constantly 'failing'. The fair and even allocation of non-renewable resources over time is a market failure issue of concern to ecological economics. This issue is also known as 'intergenerational fairness'. It is argued that the [[Market (economics)#Mechanisms of markets|market mechanism]] fails when it comes to allocating the Earth's finite mineral stock fairly and evenly among present and future generations, as future generations are not, and cannot be, present on today's market.<ref name=ngr01/>{{rp|375}} <ref name=ap01/>{{rp|142f}} In effect, today's market prices do not, and cannot, reflect the preferences of the yet unborn.<ref name=jm01/>{{rp|156–160}} This is an instance of a market failure passed unrecognized by most mainstream economists, as the concept of [[Pareto efficiency]] is entirely static (timeless).<ref name=hd02/>{{rp|181f}} Imposing government restrictions on the general level of activity in the economy may be the only way of bringing about a more fair and even intergenerational allocation of the mineral stock. Hence, [[Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen]] and [[Herman Daly]], the two leading theorists in the field, have both called for the imposition of such restrictions: Georgescu-Roegen has proposed a minimal bioeconomic program, and Daly has proposed a [[Steady-state economy#Herman Daly's concept of a steady-state economy|comprehensive steady-state economy]].<ref name=ngr01/>{{rp|374–379}} <ref name=hd02/> However, Georgescu-Roegen, Daly, and other economists in the field agree that on a finite Earth, [[Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen#Criticising Daly's steady-state economics|geologic limits will inevitably strain most fairness in the longer run]], regardless of any present government restrictions: ''Any'' rate of extraction and use of the finite stock of non-renewable mineral resources will diminish the remaining stock left over for future generations to use.<ref name=ngr01/>{{rp|366–369}} <ref name=hd01/>{{rp|369–371}} <ref name=kb01/>{{rp|165–167}} <ref name=mb01/>{{rp|270}} <ref name=av01/>{{rp|37}} Another ecological market failure is presented by the overutilisation of an otherwise renewable resource at a point in time, or within a short period of time. Such overutilisation usually occurs when the resource in question has poorly defined (or non-existing) [[Property rights (economics)|property rights]] attached to it while too many market agents engage in activity simultaneously for the resource to be able to sustain it all. Examples range from over-fishing of fisheries and over-grazing of pastures to over-crowding of recreational areas in congested cities. This type of ecological market failure is generally known as the '[[tragedy of the commons]]'. In this type of market failure, the principle of Pareto efficiency is violated the utmost, as ''all'' agents in the market are left worse off, while nobody are benefitting. It has been argued that the best way to remedy a 'tragedy of the commons'-type of ecological market failure is to establish enforceable property rights politically – only, this may be easier said than done.<ref name=hd03/>{{rp|172f}} The issue of [[climate change]] presents an overwhelming example of a 'tragedy of the commons'-type of ecological market failure: The Earth's [[Atmosphere of Earth|atmosphere]] may be regarded as a 'global common' exhibiting poorly defined (non-existing) property rights, and the waste absorption capacity of the atmosphere with regard to carbon dioxide is presently being heavily overloaded by a large volume of emissions from the [[world economy]].<ref name=cm01/>{{rp|347f}} Historically, the [[fossil fuel]] dependence of the [[Industrial Revolution]] has unintentionally thrown mankind out of ecological equilibrium with the rest of the Earth's biosphere (including the atmosphere), and the market has failed to correct the situation ever since. Quite the opposite: The unrestricted market has been exacerbating this global state of ecological ''dis''-equilibrium, and is expected to continue doing so well into the foreseeable future.<ref name=js01/>{{rp|95–101}} This particular market failure may be remedied to some extent at the political level by the establishment of an international (or regional) [[Emissions trading|cap and trade property rights system]], where [[Greenhouse gas emissions|carbon dioxide emission]] permits are bought and sold among market agents.<ref name=hd03/>{{rp|433–35}} The term '[[uneconomic growth]]' describes a pervasive ecological market failure: The ecological costs of further economic growth in a so-called 'full-world economy' like the present world economy may exceed the immediate social benefits derived from this growth.<ref name=hd03/>{{rp|16–21}} === Zerbe and McCurdy === Zerbe and McCurdy connected criticism of market failure paradigm to transaction costs. Market failure paradigm is defined as follows: "A fundamental problem with the concept of market failure, as economists occasionally recognize, is that it describes a situation that exists everywhere." Transaction costs are part of each market exchange, although the price of transaction costs is not usually determined. They occur everywhere and are unpriced. Consequently, market failures and externalities can arise in the economy every time transaction costs arise. There is no place for government intervention. Instead, government should focus on the elimination of both transaction costs and costs of provision.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=McCurdy|first1=Howard E.|last2=Zerbe|first2=Richard O. Jr.|date=1999|title=The Failure of Market Failure|journal=Journal of Policy Analysis and Management|volume=18|issue=4|pages=558–578|doi=10.1002/(SICI)1520-6688(199923)18:4<558::AID-PAM2>3.0.CO;2-U|s2cid=17174754 }}</ref> ==See also== * [[Contract failure]] * [[Criticism of capitalism]] * [[Distortion (economics)]] * [[Highest and best use]] * [[Health economics#Arguments for intervention]] * [[Public economics]] * [[Tyranny of small decisions]] * [[Tragedy of the commons]] * [[Tragedy of the anticommons]] ==References== {{reflist|30em|refs= <ref name=mb01> {{cite book |last=Bonaiuti |first=Mauro |author-link=Mauro Bonaiuti |date=2008 |chapter=Searching for a Shared Imaginary – A Systemic Approach to Degrowth and Politics |editor1-last=Flipo |editor1-first=Fabrice |editor2-last=Schneider |editor2-first=François|editor2-link=:fr:François Schneider |title=Proceedings of the First International Conference on Economic De-Growth for Ecological Sustainability and Social Equity |chapter-url=http://degrowth.org/wp-content/uploads/2011/07/Degrowth-Conference-Proceedings.pdf |chapter-format=PDF contains all conference proceedings |location=Paris }}</ref> <ref name=kb01> {{cite book |last=Boulding |first=Kenneth E. |author-link=Kenneth E. Boulding |date=1981 |title=Evolutionary Economics |url=https://archive.org/details/evolutionaryecon0000boul |url-access=registration |location=Beverly Hills |publisher=Sage Publications |isbn=0803916485 }}</ref> <ref name=hd01> {{cite book |editor-last=Daly |editor-first=Herman E.|editor-link=Herman Daly |edition=2nd |date=1980 |title=Economics, Ecology, Ethics. Essays Towards a Steady-State Economy |url=http://www.uvm.edu/~jdericks/EE/Daly_Ends_n_Means.pdf |format=PDF contains only the introductory chapter of the book |location=San Francisco |publisher=W.H. Freeman and Company |isbn=0716711788 }}</ref> <ref name=hd02> {{cite book |last=Daly |first=Herman E. |author-link=Herman Daly |edition=2nd |date=1992 |title=Steady-state economics |location=London |publisher=Earthscan Publications }}</ref> <ref name=hd03> {{cite book |last1=Daly |first1=Herman E. |last2=Farley |first2=Joshua |author-link1=Herman Daly |date=2011 |title=Ecological Economics. Principles and Applications. |edition=2nd |url=http://library.uniteddiversity.coop/Measuring_Progress_and_Eco_Footprinting/Ecological_Economics-Principles_and_Applications.pdf |format=PDF contains full textbook |location=Washington |publisher=Island Press |isbn=978-1597266819 }}</ref> <ref name=ngr01> {{cite journal |last=Georgescu-Roegen |first=Nicholas |author-link=Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen |date=1975 |title=Energy and Economic Myths |journal=Southern Economic Journal |url=http://www.uvm.edu/~jfarley/EEseminar/readings/energy%20myths.pdf|volume=41 |issue=3 |location=Tennessee |publisher=[[Southern Economic Association]] |doi=10.2307/1056148 |pages=347–381|jstor=1056148 }}</ref> journal <ref name=jm01> {{cite book |last=Martínez-Alier |first=Juan |author-link=Joan Martinez Alier |date=1987 |title=Ecological Economics: Energy, Environment and Society. |location=Oxford |publisher=Basil Blackwell |isbn=0631171460 |url-access=registration |url=https://archive.org/details/ecologicaleconom0000mart }}</ref> <ref name=cm01> {{cite book |last=McConnell |first=Campbell R. |edition=18th |date=2009 |title=Economics. Principles, Problems and Policies. |url=http://www.califaxprinters.com/mba_books/EB%20McConnell%20Econ.18e.pdf |format=PDF contains full textbook |location=New York |publisher=McGraw-Hill |display-authors=etal |isbn=978-0073375694 |access-date=2016-04-15 |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20161006014212/http://www.califaxprinters.com/mba_books/EB%20McConnell%20Econ.18e.pdf |archive-date=2016-10-06 |url-status=dead }}</ref> <ref name=ap01> {{cite book |last=Perez-Carmona |first=Alexander |date=2013 |chapter=Growth: A Discussion of the Margins of Economic and Ecological Thought |chapter-url=http://www.slideshare.net/lucieevers1/growth-in-margin-of-ecological-thought-by-perez |editor-last=Meuleman |editor-first=Louis|title=Transgovernance. Advancing Sustainability Governance. |doi=10.1007/978-3-642-28009-2_3 |via=SlideShare |location=Heidelberg |publisher=Springer |isbn=978-3642280085 |pages=83–161}}</ref> <ref name=js01> {{cite book |last=Schmitz |first=John E.J. |date=2007 |title=The Second Law of Life: Energy, Technology, and the Future of Earth As We Know It. |url=https://secondlawoflife.wordpress.com/contents |format=Link to the author's science blog, based on his textbook |location=Norwich |publisher=William Andrew Publishing |isbn=978-0815515371 }}</ref> <ref name=av01> {{cite book |last1=Valero Capilla |first1=Antonio |last2=Valero Delgado |first2=Alicia |date=2014 |title=Thanatia: The Destiny of the Earth's Mineral Resources. A Thermodynamic Cradle-to-Cradle Assessment. |url=http://www.worldscientific.com/doi/suppl/10.1142/7323/suppl_file/7323_chap01.pdf |format=PDF contains only the introductory chapter of the book |location=Singapore |publisher=World Scientific Publishing |isbn=978-9814273930 |doi=10.1142/7323 |bibcode=2014tdem.book.....C }}</ref> }} ==Further reading== * {{cite encyclopedia |last=Cowan|first=Tyler |author-link=Tyler Cowan |editor-first=Ronald |editor-last=Hamowy |editor-link=Ronald Hamowy |encyclopedia=The Encyclopedia of Libertarianism |chapter=Market Failure|chapter-url=https://sk.sagepub.com/reference/libertarianism/n191.xml|url= https://books.google.com/books?id=yxNgXs3TkJYC |doi=10.4135/9781412965811.n191 |year=2008 |publisher= [[SAGE Publishing|Sage]]; [[Cato Institute]] |location= Thousand Oaks, CA |isbn= 978-1412965804 |oclc=750831024| lccn = 2008009151 |pages=315–317 |url-access=subscription }} *D Kahneman, ''[[Thinking, Fast and Slow]]'' (2011) *E McGaughey, ‘Behavioural Economics and Labour Law’ (2014) [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=2460685 LSE Law, Society and Economy Working Papers 20/2014] *M Mazzucato, ''The Entrepreneurial State'' (2013) *[[Thomas Piketty]], ''[[Capital in the Twenty-First Century]]'' (2011) ch 9 *[[Adam Smith]], ''The Wealth of Nations]]'' (1776) Book I, chapter 8 *J Stiglitz and J Rosengard, ''The Economics of the Public Sector'' (2015) ch 4</ref> ==External links== * {{Britannica|1937869}} * [http://www.daviddfriedman.com/Academic/Price_Theory/PThy_Chapter_18/PThy_Chap_18.html Market Failures] – in Price Theory, an intermediate text by [[David D. Friedman]] {{microeconomics-footer}} {{Aspects of capitalism}} {{Authority control}} [[Category:Market failure| ]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Aspects of capitalism
(
edit
)
Template:Authority control
(
edit
)
Template:Britannica
(
edit
)
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Citation needed
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite encyclopedia
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Ecological economics
(
edit
)
Template:Main
(
edit
)
Template:Microeconomics-footer
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Rp
(
edit
)
Template:See also
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:Webarchive
(
edit
)