Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Money multiplier
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Ratio of money supply to central bank money}} {{Use dmy dates|date=June 2023}} In [[monetary economics]], the '''money multiplier''' is the ratio of the [[money supply]] to the [[monetary base]] (i.e. [[central bank]] money). In some simplified expositions, the monetary multiplier is presented as simply the [[Multiplicative inverse|reciprocal]] of the [[required reserve ratio|reserve ratio]], if any, required by the central bank. More generally, the multiplier will depend on the preferences of [[household]]s, the [[bank regulation|legal regulation]] and the business policies of [[commercial bank]]s - factors which the central bank can influence, but not control completely. Because the money multiplier theory offers a potential explanation of the ways in which the central bank can control the total money supply, it is relevant when considering monetary policy strategies that target the money supply. Historically, some central banks have tried to conduct monetary policy by targeting the money supply and its growth rate, particularly in the 1970s and 1980s. The results were not considered satisfactory, however, and starting in the early 1990s, most central banks abandoned trying to steer money growth in favour of [[Inflation targeting|targeting inflation]] directly, using changes in [[interest rate]]s as the main instrument to influence economic activity. As controlling the size of the money supply has ceased being an important goal for central bank policy generally, the money multiplier parallelly has become less relevant as a tool to understand current monetary policy. It is still often used in introductory economic textbooks, however, as a simple [[shorthand]] description of the connections between central bank policies and the money supply. == Definition == The money multiplier is normally presented in the context of some simple [[Accounting identity|accounting identities]]:<ref name=Goodhart/><ref name="maninter">{{Harv|Mankiw|2022|loc=Chapter 4, Section 3: How Central Banks Influence the Money Supply, pp. 85–92]}}</ref> Usually, the [[money supply]] (''M'') is defined as consisting of two components: [[cash|(physical) currency]] (''C'') and [[deposit account]]s (''D'') held by the general public. By definition, therefore: <math>M = D+C.</math> Additionally, the [[monetary base]] (''B'') (also known as high-powered money) is normally defined as the sum of currency held by the general public (''C'') and the [[Bank reserves|reserves of the banking sector]] (held either as currency in the vaults of the [[commercial bank]]s or as deposits at the [[central bank]]) (''R''): <math>B = R+C.</math> Rearranging these two definitions result in a third identity: <math>M =\frac{1+C/D}{R/D + C/D}B.</math><ref name=Goodhart/> This relation describes the money supply in terms of the level of base money and two ratios: R/D is the ratio of commercial banks' reserves to deposit accounts, and C/D is the general public's ratio of currency to deposits. As the relation is an identity, it holds true by definition, so that a change in the money supply can always be expressed in terms of these three variables alone. This may be advantageous because it is a simple way of summarising money supply changes, but the use of the identity does not in itself provide a behavioural theory of what determines the money supply.<ref name=Goodhart/> If, however, one additionally assumes that the two ratios C/D and R/D are [[exogenous]]ly determined constants, the equation implies that the central bank can control the money supply by controlling the monetary base via [[open-market operations]]: In this case, when the monetary base increases by, say, $1, the money supply will increase by $(1+C/D)/(R/D + C/D). This is the central contents of the money multiplier theory, and <math>\frac{1+C/D}{R/D + C/D}</math> is the money multiplier,<ref name=Goodhart/><ref name="maninter"/> a [[multiplier (economics)|multiplier]] being a factor that measures how much an endogenous variable (in this case, the money supply) changes in response to a change in some exogenous variable (in this case, the money base). In some textbook applications, the relationship is simplified by assuming that cash does not exist so that the public holds money only in the form of bank deposits. In that case, the currency-deposit ratio C/D equals zero, and the money multipli <math>\frac{1}{R/D}.</math><ref name="krugmacro">{{Harv|Krugman|Wells|2009|loc=Chapter 14: Money, Banking, and the Federal Reserve System: Reserves, Bank Deposits, and the Money Multiplier, [https://books.google.com/books?id=dpTBdNGGrtUC&pg=PA393 pp. 393–396] }}</ref> Empirically, the money multiplier can be found as the ratio of some broad money aggregate like [[M2 (economics)|M2]] over [[M0 (economics)|M0]] (base money).<ref name="krugact">{{Harv|Krugman|Wells|2009|loc=[https://books.google.com/books?id=dpTBdNGGrtUC&pg=PA395&q=actual%20money%20multiplier p. 395]}} calls the empirically observed multiplier the "actual money multiplier".</ref> ==Interpretation== Generally, the currency-deposit ratio C/D reflects the preferences of [[household]]s about the form of money they wish to hold (currency versus deposits). The reserve-deposit ratio R/D will be determined by the business policies of commercial banks and the [[Bank regulation|laws regulating banks]].<ref name="maninter"/>{{rp|86}} [[Benjamin M. Friedman|Benjamin Friedman]] in his chapter on the [[money supply]] in ''[[The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics]]'' writes that both central bank reserves (supplied by the central bank and demanded by the commercial banks for several reasons) and deposits (supplied by commercial banks and demanded by households and non-financial firms) are traded in markets with equilibria of demand and supply which depend on the interest rate as well as a number of other factors. Consequently, the money multiplier representation should be interpreted as "really just a [[shorthand]] simplification that works well or badly depending on the strength of the relevant interest elasticities and the extent of variation in interest rates and the many other factors involved."<ref name="Palgrave">{{cite book |last1=Friedman |authorlink1 = Benjamin M. Friedman |first1=Benjamin M. |chapter=Money Supply |chapter-url=https://link.springer.com/referenceworkentry/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_875-2 |title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK |pages=1–10 |language=en |doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_875-2 |date=2017|isbn=978-1-349-95121-5 }}</ref> ===The importance of excess reserves=== In some presentations of the money multiplier theory, the further simplification is made that commercial banks only hold the reserves that are legally required by the monetary authorities so that the R/D ratio is determined directly by the central banks.<ref name="krugmacro"/> In many countries the monetary authorities maintain [[reserve requirement]]s that secure a minimum level of reserves at all times. However, commercial banks may often hold [[excess reserves]], i.e. reserves held in excess of the legal reserve requirements. This is for instance the case in countries that do not impose legal [[Reserve requirement#Reserve requirements by country|reserve requirements]] at all like the United States,<ref name="RIP MM">{{cite web |last1=Ihrig |first1=Jane |last2=Weinbach |first2=Gretchen C. |last3=Wolla |first3=Scott A. |title=Teaching the Linkage Between Banks and the Fed: R.I.P. Money Multiplier |url=https://research.stlouisfed.org/publications/page1-econ/2021/09/17/teaching-the-linkage-between-banks-and-the-fed-r-i-p-money-multiplier |website=research.stlouisfed.org |publisher=Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis |access-date=4 August 2023 |language=en |date=September 2021}}</ref><ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.forbes.com/sites/bobhaber/2020/03/16/the-fed-fires-the-big-one/|title=The Fed Fires 'The Big One'|first=Bob|last=Haber|website=Forbes|accessdate=30 June 2023}}</ref> the United Kingdom, Canada, Australia, New Zealand and the Scandinavian countries.<ref name="imf.org">{{cite web|url=https://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2011/wp1136.pdf|title=Central Bank Balances and Reserve Requirements|author=Simon Gray |website=IMF|access-date=19 July 2023}}</ref><ref>Even in those countries that do, the reserve requirement is as a ratio to deposits held, not a ratio to loans that can be extended.{{cite web |url=http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs189.pdf |title=Basel III: A global regulatory framework for more resilient banks and banking systems |date=December 2010|website=bis.org|access-date=19 July 2023}} [[Basel III]] does stipulate a liquidity requirement to cover 30 days net cash outflow expected under a modeled stressed scenario (note this is not a ratio to loans that can be extended); however, liquidity coverage does not need to be held as reserves but rather as any high-quality liquid assets.{{cite web|url=http://www.bis.org/publ/bcbs238.pdf|title=Basel III: The Liquidity Coverage Ratio and liquidity risk monitoring tools |date=January 2013|website=bis.org|access-date=19 July 2023}}{{cite web |url=http://www.bis.org/bcbs/basel3/b3summarytable.pdf|title=Basel Committee on Banking Supervision reforms - Basel III|website=bis.org|access-date=19 July 2023}}</ref> The possibility of banks voluntarily choosing to hold excess reserves, in amounts that may change over time as the opportunity costs for banks change, are one reason why the monetary multiplier may not be stable. For instance, following the introduction of interest rates on excess reserves in the US, a large growth in excess reserves occurred in the [[2008 financial crisis]], US bank excess reserves growing over 500-fold, from under $2 billion in August 2008 to over $1,000 billion<!-- Please leave as 1,000 billion, not as 1 trillion, as otherwise the scale of increase is unclear, because one does not mentally compare “billion” to “trillion”; please see http://xkcd.com/558/ for an illustration. --> in November 2009.<ref>[http://research.stlouisfed.org/fred2/series/EXCRESNS EXCRESNS] series, St. Louis Fed</ref><ref>{{cite news | url=https://krugman.blogs.nytimes.com/2009/12/14/followup-on-samuelson-and-monetary-policy/ | title=Followup on Samuelson and monetary policy | first=Paul | last=Krugman | authorlink=Paul Krugman | newspaper=[[New York Times]] | date=14 December 2009}}</ref> The insight that banks may adjust their reserve/deposit ratio endogenously, making the money multiplier unstable, is old. [[Paul Samuelson]] noted in his [[Economics (textbook)|bestselling textbook]] in 1948 that: {{blockquote|By increasing the volume of their government securities and loans and by lowering Member Bank legal reserve requirements, the Reserve Banks can encourage an increase in the supply of money and bank deposits. They can encourage but, without taking drastic action, they cannot ''compel.'' For in the middle of a deep depression just when we want Reserve policy to be most effective, the Member Banks are likely to be timid about buying new investments or making loans. If the Reserve authorities buy government bonds in the open market and thereby swell bank reserves, the banks will not put these funds to work but will simply hold reserves. Result: no 5 for 1, “no nothing,” simply a substitution on the bank’s balance sheet of idle cash for old government bonds.|{{Harv|Samuelson|1948|loc=pp. 353–354}}}} Restated, increases in central bank money may not result in commercial bank money because the money is not ''required'' to be lent out – it may instead result in a growth of unlent (i.e. excess) reserves. This situation has been referred to as "[[pushing on a string]]": withdrawal of central bank money ''compels'' commercial banks to curtail lending (one can ''pull'' money via this mechanism), but input of central bank money does not compel commercial banks to lend (one cannot ''push'' via this mechanism).<ref>{{cite news |last1=Blyth |first1=Mark |author-link=Mark Blyth |title=The Last Days of Pushing on a String |url=https://hbr.org/2012/08/the-last-days-of-pushing-on-a |access-date=19 October 2023 |work=Harvard Business Review |date=7 August 2012}}</ref> The amount of its assets that a bank chooses to hold as excess reserves is a decreasing function of the amount by which the market rate for loans to the general public from commercial banks exceeds the interest rate on excess reserves and of the amount by which the market rate for loans to other banks (in the US, the [[federal funds rate]]) exceeds the interest rate on excess reserves. Since the money multiplier in turn depends negatively on the desired reserve/deposit ratio, the money multiplier depends positively on these two opportunity costs. Moreover, the public’s choice of the currency/deposit ratio depends negatively on market rates of return on highly liquid substitutes for currency; since the currency ratio negatively affects the money multiplier, the money multiplier is positively affected by the return on these substitutes. Note that when making predictions assuming a constant multiplier, the predictions are valid only if these ratios do not in fact change. Sometimes this holds, and sometimes it does not; for example, increases in central bank money (i.e. base money) may result in increases in commercial bank money – and will, if these ratios (and thus multiplier) stay constant – or may result in increases in excess reserves but little or no change in commercial bank money, in which case the reserve–deposit ratio will grow and the multiplier will fall.<ref>{{Harv|Mankiw|2002|loc=[https://books.google.com/books?id=B-iNoOEoSnkC&pg=PA489&q=fall%20in%20the%20money%20multiplier p. 489]}}</ref> === "Loans first" model === An alternative interpretation of the direction of causality in the identity described above is that the connection between the money supply and the monetary base goes from the former to the latter: Interest-rate-targeting central banks supply whatever amount of reserves that the banking system demands, given the reserve requirements and the amount of deposits that have been created.<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.hks.harvard.edu/sites/default/files/centers/mrcbg/programs/senior.fellows/2019-20%20fellows/BanksCannotLendOutReservesAug2013_%20(002).pdf|title=Repeat After Me: Banks Cannot And Do Not "Lend Out" Reserves|last=Sheard|first=Paul|date=2013-08-13|website=[[Standard & Poor's]]|url-status=live|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191114194230/https://www.hks.harvard.edu/sites/default/files/centers/mrcbg/programs/senior.fellows/2019-20%20fellows/BanksCannotLendOutReservesAug2013_%20(002).pdf|archive-date=2019-11-14|access-date=2019-11-14}}</ref> In this alternative model of money creation, loans are first extended by commercial banks – say, $1,000 of loans, which may then require that the bank borrow $100 of reserves either from depositors or other private sources of financing, or from the central bank. This view is advanced in [[endogenous money]] theories.<ref name=Abel/> It is also occasionally referred to as a "Loans first" model as opposed to the traditional multiplier theory, which can be labelled a "Reserves first" model.<ref>{{cite web |last1=Rendahl |first1=Pontus |last2=Freund |first2=Lukas B. |title=Banks do not create money out of thin air |url=https://cepr.org/voxeu/columns/banks-do-not-create-money-out-thin-air |website=CEPR |access-date=19 October 2023 |language=en |date=14 December 2019}}</ref> == Monetary policy in practice == {{See also|Monetary policy}} Whereas used in many textbooks, the realism of the money multiplier theory is questioned by several economists, and it is generally rejected as a useful description of actual central bank behaviour today, partly because major central banks generally have not tried to control the monetary supply during the last decades, hence making the theory irrelevant, partly because it is doubtful as to how large an extent the central banks would be able to control the money supply, should they wish to. The last question is a matter of the stability of the money multiplier. ===Historical attempts to steer the money supply=== Historically, central banks have in some periods used strategies of trying to target a certain level or growth rate of money supply, in particular during the late 1970s and 1980s, inspired by [[monetarism|monetarist theory]] and the [[quantity theory of money]].<ref name="Historical">{{cite web |title=Federal Reserve Board - Historical Approaches to Monetary Policy |url=https://www.federalreserve.gov/monetarypolicy/historical-approaches-to-monetary-policy.htm |website=Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System |access-date=19 October 2023 |language=en |date=8 March 2018}}</ref><ref>{{cite web | first = Ben | last = Bernanke | author-link = Ben Bernanke | title = Monetary Aggregates and Monetary Policy at the Federal Reserve: A Historical Perspective | publisher = Federal Reserve | year = 2006 | url = http://www.federalreserve.gov/newsevents/speech/bernanke20061110a.htm }}</ref> However, these strategies turned out to not work very well and were abandoned again.<ref name=Blanchard/> In the United States, short-term interest rates became fourfould more volatile during the years 1979-1982 when the Federal Reserve adopted a moderate version of monetary base control, and the targeted monetary aggregate at the time, M1, even increased its short-term volatility.<ref name=Goodhart>{{cite book |last1=Goodhart |first1=Charles |author-link1= Charles Goodhart |title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |date=2016 |publisher=Palgrave Macmillan UK |isbn=978-1-349-95121-5 |pages=1–5 |chapter-url=https://link.springer.com/referenceworkentry/10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_997-1 |access-date=19 October 2023 |language=en |chapter=Monetary Base|doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_997-1 }}</ref> ===Current monetary policy=== Starting in the early 1990s, a fundamental rethinking of monetary policy took place in major central banks, shifting to [[inflation targeting|targeting inflation]] rather than monetary growth and generally using interest rates to implement goals rather than quantitative measures like holding the quantity of base money at fixed levels.<ref name=Blanchard>Blanchard et al. 2017.</ref>{{rp|484–485}} As a result, modern central banks hardly ever conduct their policies by trying to control the money supply,<ref>Romer 2019, p. 608. Quote:''Because of these difficulties, modern central banks almost never conduct policy by trying to achieve some target growth rate for the money stock. Instead, their normal policies focus on adjusting the short-term nominal interest rate in response to various disturbances.''</ref> implying also that the monetary multiplier theory has become more irrelevant as a tool to understand current monetary policy.<ref name="RIP MM"/><ref name=Ihrig>{{cite journal |last1=Ihrig |first1=Jane |last2=Weinbach |first2=Gretchen |last3=Wolla |first3=Scott |title=How are Banks and the Fed Linked? Teaching Key Concepts Today |journal=Review of Political Economy |date=3 April 2023 |volume=35 |issue=2 |pages=555–571 |doi=10.1080/09538259.2022.2040906 |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/09538259.2022.2040906 |access-date=19 October 2023 |language=en |issn=0953-8259}}</ref> [[Charles Goodhart]] notes in his chapter on the [[monetary base]] in ''The New Palgrave'' that the banking system has virtually never worked in the way hypothesized by the monetary multiplier theory. Instead, central banks have used their powers to effect a desired level of interest rates rather than achieve a pre-determined quantity of monetary base or of some monetary aggregate. He also mentions that the institutional development of the [[financial market]]s, notably [[interbank lending market]]s, implies that the monetary base multiplier no longer would, or could, work in the textbook fashion. Instead, he argues that the behavioural process leading to a change in monetary bases runs from an initial change in interest rates to a subsequent readjustment in monetary aggregate quantities, endogenously determining these as well as the accommodating monetary base.<ref name=Goodhart/> Also [[David Romer]] notes in his graduate textbook "''Advanced Macroeconomics''" that it is difficult for central banks to control broad monetary aggregates like M2, causing central banks generally to assign the behaviour of the money supply an unimportant role in policy, focusing instead on adjusting nominal interest rates to stabilize the economy.<ref>Romer 2019, pp. 607-608. Quote:''The measures of the money stock that the central bank can control tightly, such as [[high-powered money]], are not closely linked to [[aggregate demand]]. And the measures of the money stock that are sometimes closely linked with aggregate demand, such as ''M2'', are difficult for the central bank to control.''</ref> [[Greg Mankiw|Gregory Mankiw]], author of one of the widely read intermediate textbooks (''Macroeconomics'') that present the money multiplier theory, notes in its 11th edition that even though the Federal Reserve can influence the money supply, it cannot control it fully because households' decisions and banks' discretion in the conduct of their business may change the money supply in ways unanticipated by the central bank.<ref name="maninter"/> After the [[2008 financial crisis]], several central banks, including the [[Federal Reserve]],<ref name="RIP MM"/> [[Bank of England]],<ref name="boe">{{Cite web|url=http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/quarterly-bulletin/2014/q1/money-creation-in-the-modern-economy|title=Money creation in the modern economy|last1=McLeay|first1=Michael|last2=Radia|first2=Amar|date=14 March 2014|website=[[Bank of England]]|url-status=live|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20191112182432/https://www.bankofengland.co.uk/quarterly-bulletin/2014/q1/money-creation-in-the-modern-economy|archive-date=2019-11-12|access-date=2019-11-14|last3=Thomas|first3=Ryland}}</ref> [[Deutsche Bundesbank]],<ref>{{Cite web|url=https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/654284/df66c4444d065a7f519e2ab0c476df58/mL/2017-04-money-creation-process-data.pdf|title=The role of banks, non- banks and the central bank in the money creation process|website=[[Deutsche Bundesbank]]|series=Monthly Report April 2017/13|url-status=live|archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20190917181144/https://www.bundesbank.de/resource/blob/654284/df66c4444d065a7f519e2ab0c476df58/mL/2017-04-money-creation-process-data.pdf|archive-date=2019-09-17|access-date=2019-11-16}}</ref> the [[Hungarian National Bank]]<ref name=Abel>{{cite journal |last1=Ábel |first1=István |last2=Lehmann |first2=Kristóf |last3=Tapaszti |first3=Attila |title=The controversial treatment of money and banks in macroeconomics |journal=Financial and Economic Review |date=June 2016 |volume=15 |issue=2 |pages=33–58 |url=https://en-hitelintezetiszemle.mnb.hu/letoltes/istvan-abel-kristof-lehmann-attila-tapaszti-en.pdf |access-date=19 October 2023}}</ref> and [[Danmarks Nationalbank]]<ref>{{cite journal |title=Penge, kredit og bankvæsen |journal=Nationalbanken.dk |date=23 September 2014 |url=https://www.nationalbanken.dk/da/viden-og-nyheder/publikationer-og-taler/arkiv-publikationer/2014/penge-kredit-og-bankvaesen |access-date=19 October 2023 |language=da}}</ref> have issued explanations of money creation supporting the view that central banks generally do not control the creation of money, nor do they try to, though their interest rate-setting monetary policies naturally affect the amount of loans and deposits that commercial banks create. The Federal Reserve in 2021 launched several educational resources to facilitate teaching the conduct of current monetary policy, recommending teachers to avoid relying on the money multiplier concept, which was described as obsolete and unusable.<ref>{{cite web |title=Teaching the New Tools of Monetary Policy in an Ample-reserves Framework |url=https://www.stlouisfed.org/education/teaching-new-tools-of-monetary-policy |website=www.stlouisfed.org |access-date=19 October 2023 |language=en}}</ref><ref name=Ihrig/><ref>{{cite journal |last1=Ihrig |first1=Jane |last2=Wolla |first2=Scott |title=Teaching Monetary Policy with Ample Reserves |journal=Journal of Economics Teaching |date=2023 |pages=114–127 |doi=10.58311/jeconteach/6f8dff11179466b2d32da497c5465b9cff2774ac|doi-access=free }}</ref> Jaromir Benes and [[Michael Kumhof]] of the IMF Research Department, argue that: the "deposit multiplier" of the undergraduate economics textbook, where monetary aggregates are created at the initiative of the central bank, through an initial injection of high-powered money into the banking system that gets multiplied through bank lending, turns the actual operation of the [[monetary transmission mechanism]] on its head. At all times, when banks ask for reserves, the central bank obliges. According to this model, reserves therefore impose no constraint and the deposit multiplier is therefore a myth. The authors therefore argue that private banks are almost fully in control of the money creation process.<ref>{{cite web |url=http://www.imf.org/external/pubs/ft/wp/2012/wp12202.pdf|title=The Chicago Plan Revisited|date=August 2012|author1=Jaromir Benes |author2=Michael Kumhof|website=IMF|access-date=19 July 2023}}</ref> Besides the mainstream questioning of the usefulness of the money multiplier theory, the rejection of this theory has also been a theme in the [[Heterodox economics|heterodox]] [[post-Keynesian]] [[Schools of economic thought|school of economic thought]].<ref name=Ihrig/> ==Example== As explained above, according to the monetary multiplier theory money creation in a fractional-reserve banking system occurs when a given reserve is lent out by a bank, then deposited at a bank (possibly different), which is then lent out again, the process repeating<ref name="maninter" /> and the ultimate result being a [[geometric series]]. The following formula for the money multiplier may be used, explicitly accounting for the fact that the public has a desire to hold some currency in the form of cash and that commercial banks may desire to hold reserves in excess of the legal reserve requirements: :<math>m=\frac{(1+Currency/Deposit Ratio)}{(Currency/Deposit Ratio + Desired Reserve Ratio)}.</math> Here the Desired Reserve Ratio is the sum of the required reserve ratio and the excess reserve ratio. The formula above is derived from the following procedure. Let the monetary base be normalized to unity. Define the legal reserve ratio, <math>\alpha \in\left(0, 1\right)\;</math>, the excess reserves ratio, <math>\beta \in\left(0, 1\right)\;</math>, the currency/deposit ratio with respect to deposits, <math>\gamma \in\left(0, 1\right)\;</math>; suppose the demand for funds is unlimited; then the theoretical superior limit for deposits is defined by the following series: <div style="text-align:center;"><math>Deposits = \sum_{n = 0}^{\infty}\left[\left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)\right]^{n} = \frac{1}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math></div>. Analogously, the theoretical superior limit for the money held by public is defined by the following series: <div style="text-align:center;"><math>Publicly Held Currency = \gamma \cdot Deposits = \frac{\gamma}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math></div> and the theoretical superior limit for the total loans lent in the market is defined by the following series: <div style="text-align:center;"><math>Loans = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta\right) \cdot Deposits = \frac{1 - \alpha - \beta}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math></div> By summing up the two quantities, the theoretical money multiplier is defined as <div style="text-align:center;"><math>m = \frac{Money Stock}{Monetary Base} = \frac{Deposits + Publicly Held Currency}{Monetary Base} = \frac{1 + \gamma}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math></div> where {{math|1={{var|α}} + {{var|β}} = ''Desired Reserve Ratio''}} and <math>\gamma = currency/deposit</math> The process described above by the geometric series can be represented in the following table, where *loans at stage <math>k\;</math> are a function of the deposits at the preceding stage: <math>L_{k} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta\right) \cdot D_{k - 1}</math> *publicly held money at stage <math>k\;</math> is a function of the deposits at the preceding stage: <math>PHM_{k} = \gamma \cdot D_{k - 1}</math> *deposits at stage <math>k\;</math> are the difference between additional loans and publicly held money relative to the same stage: <math>D_{k} = L_{k} - PHM_{k}\;</math> {| class="wikitable" |+ Process of money multiplication ! {{math|{{var|n}}}} ! Deposits ! Loans ! Publicly held money |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <math>n = 0\;</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>D_{0} = 1\;</math> | align="CENTER" | - | align="CENTER" | - |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <math>n = 1\;</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>D_{1} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>L_{1} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta\right)</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>PHM_{1} = \gamma\;</math> |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <math>n = 2\;</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>D_{2} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^2</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>L_{2} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta\right) \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>PHM_{2} = \gamma \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)</math> |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <math>n = 3\;</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>D_{3} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^3</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>L_{3} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta\right) \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^2</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>PHM_{3} = \gamma \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^2</math> |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | … | align="CENTER" | … | align="CENTER" | … | align="CENTER" | … |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <math>n = k\;</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>D_{k} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^k</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>L_{k} = \left(1 - \alpha - \beta\right) \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^{k - 1}</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>PHM_{k} = \gamma \left(1 - \alpha - \beta - \gamma\right)^{k - 1}</math> |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | … | align="CENTER" | … | align="CENTER" | … | align="CENTER" | … |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <math>n \rightarrow \infty</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>D_{\infty} = 0</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>L_{\infty} = 0</math> | align="LEFT" | <math>PHM_{\infty} = 0</math> |- | height="32" align="CENTER" | <br /> | align="LEFT" | <br /> | align="LEFT" | <br /> | align="LEFT" | <br /> |- | <br /> | align="CENTER" | '''Total deposits:''' | align="CENTER" | '''Total loans:''' | align="CENTER" | '''Total publicly held money:''' |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <br /> | align="CENTER" | <math>D = \frac{1}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math> | align="CENTER" | <math>L = \frac{1 - \alpha - \beta}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math> | align="CENTER" | <math>PHM = \frac{\gamma}{\alpha + \beta + \gamma}</math> |- |} === Table === This re-lending process (assuming that no currency is used) can be depicted as follows, assuming a 20% reserve ratio and a $100 initial deposit: {| class="wikitable" ! Individual bank ! Amount deposited ! Lent out ! Reserves |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | A | bgcolor="#00AA00" align="CENTER" | 100.00 | align="CENTER" | 80.00 | align="CENTER" | 20.00 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | B | align="CENTER" | 80.00 | align="CENTER" | 64.00 | align="CENTER" | 16.00 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | C | align="CENTER" | 64.00 | align="CENTER" | 51.20 | align="CENTER" | 12.80 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | D | align="CENTER" | 51.20 | align="CENTER" | 40.96 | align="CENTER" | 10.24 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | E | align="CENTER" | 40.96 | align="CENTER" | 32.77 | align="CENTER" | 8.19 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | F | align="CENTER" | 32.77 | align="CENTER" | 26.21 | align="CENTER" | 6.55 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | G | align="CENTER" | 26.21 | align="CENTER" | 20.97 | align="CENTER" | 5.24 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | H | align="CENTER" | 20.97 | align="CENTER" | 16.78 | align="CENTER" | 4.19 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | I | align="CENTER" | 16.78 | align="CENTER" | 13.42 | align="CENTER" | 3.36 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | J | align="CENTER" | 13.42 | align="CENTER" | 10.74 | align="CENTER" | 2.68 |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | K | bgcolor="#FF0000" align="CENTER" | 10.74 | align="CENTER" | <br /> | align="CENTER" | <br /> |- | height="32" align="CENTER" colspan=3 | <br /> | align="CENTER" | '''Total reserves:''' |- | height="16" align="CENTER" colspan=3 | <br /> | bgcolor="#FF0000" align="CENTER" | 89.26 |- | <br /> | align="CENTER" | '''Total amount of deposits:''' | align="CENTER" | '''Total amount lent out:''' | align="CENTER" | '''Total reserves + last amount deposited:''' |- | height="16" align="CENTER" | <br /> | bgcolor="#99CCFF" align="CENTER" | 457.05 | bgcolor="#99CCFF" align="CENTER" | 357.05 | bgcolor="#00AA00" align="CENTER" | 100.00 |- | colspan=4 |Table sources:<ref>Table created with the OpenOffice.org Calc spreadsheet program using data and information from the references listed.</ref><ref name="mdc">Federal Reserve Education - How does the Fed Create Money? {{cite web |url=http://www.federalreserveeducation.org/fed101_html/policy/money_print.htm |title=Federal Reserve Education |accessdate=2009-12-21 |url-status=dead |archiveurl=https://web.archive.org/web/20100106002902/http://federalreserveeducation.org/fed101_html/policy/money_print.htm |archivedate=2010-01-06 }} :See the link to "The Principle of Multiple Deposit Creation" pdf document towards bottom of page.</ref><ref name="nyfed">An explanation of how it works from the New York Regional Reserve Bank of the US Federal Reserve system. Scroll down to the "Reserve Requirements and Money Creation" section. Here is what it says: :"Reserve requirements affect the potential of the banking system to create transaction deposits. If the reserve requirement is 10%, for example, a bank that receives a $100 deposit may lend out $90 of that deposit. If the borrower then writes a check to someone who deposits the $90, the bank receiving that deposit can lend out $81. As the process continues, the banking system can expand the initial deposit of $100 into a maximum of $1,000 of money ($100+$90+81+$72.90+...=$1,000). In contrast, with a 20% reserve requirement, the banking system would be able to expand the initial $100 deposit into a maximum of $500 ($100+$80+$64+$51.20+...=$500). Thus, higher reserve requirements should result in reduced money creation and, in turn, in reduced economic activity." The link to this page is: http://www.newyorkfed.org/aboutthefed/fedpoint/fed45.html</ref><ref>Bank for International Settlements - The Role of Central Bank Money in Payment Systems. See page 9, titled, "The coexistence of central and commercial bank monies: multiple issuers, one currency": http://www.bis.org/publ/cpss55.pdf A quick quote in reference to the 2 different types of money is listed on page 3. It is the first sentence of the document: :"Contemporary monetary systems are based on the mutually reinforcing roles of central bank money and commercial bank monies."</ref> |- |} Note that no matter how many times the smaller and smaller amounts of money are re-lended, the legal reserve requirement is never exceeded - because that would be illegal. ==See also== * [[Deficit spending]] * [[Economic growth]] * [[Economic value added]] * [[Helicopter money]] * [[Inflation targeting]] * [[Quantitative tightening]] == References == {{Reflist}} == Sources == {{refbegin}} * {{cite book |last1=Blanchard |first1=Olivier |author-link1=Olivier Blanchard |last2=Amighini |first2=Alessia |last3=Giavazzi |first3=Francesco |author-link3=Francesco Giavazzi |title=Macroeconomics: a European perspective |date=2017 |publisher=Pearson |isbn=978-1-292-08567-8 |edition=3rd}} * {{Citation | authorlink1 = Paul Krugman | first1 = Paul | title = Macroeconomics | last1 = Krugman | first2 = Robin | last2 = Wells | year = 2009 | publisher = Macmillan | isbn = 978-0-7167-7161-6 }} * {{Citation | authorlink = N. Gregory Mankiw | first = N. Gregory | last = Mankiw | title = Macroeconomics | year = 2002 | publisher = Worth Publishers | edition = 5th | isbn = 978-0-7167-5237-0 | url-access = registration | url = https://archive.org/details/macroeconomics00mank_0 }} * {{Citation | authorlink = N. Gregory Mankiw | first = N. Gregory | last = Mankiw | title = Macroeconomics | year = 2022 | publisher = Worth Publishers | edition = 11th | isbn = 978-1-319-26390-4 }} * {{cite book |last1=Romer |first1=David |author-link=David Romer |title=Advanced macroeconomics |date=2019 |publisher=McGraw-Hill |location=New York, NY |isbn=978-1-260-18521-8 |edition=Fifth }} * {{Citation | last = Samuelson | first = Paul | title = Economics | year = 1948 | title-link = Economics (textbook) }} {{refend}} {{Authority control}} {{DEFAULTSORT:Money Multiplier}} [[Category:Monetary policy]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Authority control
(
edit
)
Template:Blockquote
(
edit
)
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite news
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Comma separated entries
(
edit
)
Template:Harv
(
edit
)
Template:Main other
(
edit
)
Template:Math
(
edit
)
Template:Refbegin
(
edit
)
Template:Refend
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Rp
(
edit
)
Template:See also
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:Use dmy dates
(
edit
)