Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Random ballot
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Electoral system with lottery among ballots}} {{Electoral systems}} A '''random ballot''' or '''random dictatorship''' is a [[Fractional social choice|randomized electoral system]] where the election is decided on the basis of a single randomly-selected ballot.<ref>{{Cite journal|last1=Sewell|first1=Roger|last2=MacKay|first2=David|last3=McLean|first3=Iain|date=January 2009|title=Probabilistic electoral methods, representative probability, and maximum entropy|url=http://www.inference.org.uk/mackay/vote/abstract.html|journal=Voting Matters|volume=26|pages=22|quote=A voter is picked at random and the output ordering of the election is set to be the ordering given by that voter.}}</ref><ref>{{Cite journal|last=Zeckhauser|first=Richard|date=1973|title=Voting Systems, Honest Preferences and Pareto Optimality|journal=American Political Science Review|language=en|volume=67|issue=3|pages=938β940|doi=10.2307/1958635|issn=0003-0554|jstor=1958635|s2cid=147293110 |quote=Each individual writes the name of a candidate on a ballot. The voters' ballots are collected and placed in a revolving drum. After shuffling, a ballot is chosen at random. The name on the chosen ballot is the elected candidate.}}</ref> A closely-related variant is called '''random serial''' (or '''sequential''') '''dictatorship''', which repeats the procedure and draws another ballot if multiple candidates are tied on the first ballot. Random dictatorship was first described in 1977 by [[Allan Gibbard]], who showed it to be the unique social choice rule that [[Anonymity (social choice)|treats all voters equally]] while still being [[strategyproof]] in all situations.<ref>{{Cite journal|last=Gibbard|first=Allan|date=1973|title=Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result|journal=Econometrica|volume=41|issue=4|pages=592β593|doi=10.2307/1914083|issn=0012-9682|jstor=1914083|s2cid=17069971 |quote=In other words, each voter writes his first choice on a ballot; a single ballot is drawn at random; and the choice on that ballot is selected.}}</ref> Its application to elections was first described in 1984 by [[Akhil Reed Amar]].<ref>{{cite journal |author=Akhil Reed Amar |date=June 1984 |title=Choosing representatives by lottery voting |volume=93 |issue=7 |journal=[[Yale Law Journal]] |pages=1283β1308 |url=http://www.law.yale.edu/documents/pdf/1984Choosing.pdf |jstor=796258 |url-status=dead |archive-url=https://web.archive.org/web/20060831192620/http://www.law.yale.edu/documents/pdf/1984Choosing.pdf |archive-date=2006-08-31 |author-link=Akhil Reed Amar |doi=10.2307/796258 }}</ref> The rule is rarely, if ever, proposed as a genuine electoral system, as such a method (in [[Allan Gibbard|Gibbard]]'s words) "leaves too much to chance".<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Gibbard |first=Allan |date=1973 |title=Manipulation of Voting Schemes: A General Result |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1914083 |journal=Econometrica |volume=41 |issue=4 |pages=587β601 |doi=10.2307/1914083 |jstor=1914083 |issn=0012-9682|url-access=subscription }}</ref> However, the rule is often used as a tiebreaker to encourage voters to cast honest ballots, and is sometimes discussed as a [[thought experiment]].<ref>{{cite web |author=Akhil Reed Amar |author-link=Akhil Reed Amar |date=1 January 1995 |title=Lottery Voting: A Thought Experiment |url=http://digitalcommons.law.yale.edu/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=1963&context=fss_papers}}</ref> == Random dictatorship and random serial dictatorship == The dictatorship rule is obviously unfair, but it has a variant that is fair in expectation. In the '''random dictatorship (RD)''' rule, one of the voters is selected uniformly at random, and the alternative most preferred by that voter is selected. This is one of the common rules for [[random social choice]]. When used in multi-constituency bodies, it is sometimes called [[random ballot]]. Similarly to dictatorship, random dictatorship too should handle the possibility of indifferences; the common solution is to extend it to '''random serial dictatorship (RSD),'''<ref name=":0">{{Cite book |last=Felix Brandt |title=Trends in Computational Social Choice |date=2017-10-26 |publisher=Lulu.com |isbn=978-1-326-91209-3 |editor-last=Endriss |editor-first=Ulle |language=en |chapter=Probabilistic Social Choice |chapter-url=https://books.google.com/books?id=0qY8DwAAQBAJ&dq=multiwinner++voting+a+new+challenge&pg=PA27}}</ref>{{Rp|6}} also called '''random priority'''. In this mechanism, a [[random permutation]] of the voters is selected, and each voter in turn narrows the existing alternatives to the ones they most prefer, from the ones still available. It is a common mechanism in allocating indivisible objects among agents; see [[random priority item allocation]]. ===Properties=== [[Allan Gibbard]] proved the '''random dictatorship theorem'''.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Gibbard |first=Allan |date=1977 |title=Manipulation of Schemes that Mix Voting with Chance |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1911681 |journal=Econometrica |volume=45 |issue=3 |pages=665β681 |doi=10.2307/1911681 |issn=0012-9682 |jstor=1911681 |hdl-access=free |hdl=10419/220534}}</ref> It says that RD is the only rule that satisfies the following three properties: * [[Anonymity (social choice)|'''Anonymity''']]: the lottery does not discriminate in advance between different voters. * '''[[Strategyproofness]]''': any false report by an agent results in an outcome that is weakly [[Stochastic dominance|stochastically dominated]]. * [[Pareto-efficiency|'''Ex post Pareto-efficiency''']]: the outcome is Pareto-efficient. ** In fact, with strict preferences, RD satisfies a stronger efficiency property called ''SD-efficiency'': the resulting lottery is not stochastically dominated. With weak preferences, RSD satisfies ex-post efficiency, but violates SD-efficiency. ** Even with strict preferences, RD violates the stronger property called PC-efficiency: the resulting lottery might be dominated in the sense of pairwise-comparisons (for each agent, the probability that another lottery yields a better alternative than the RD lottery is larger than the other way around). RD also satisfies a property called agenda consistency. It is the only rule satisfying the following properties:<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Pattanaik |first1=Prasanta K. |last2=Peleg |first2=Bezalel |date=1986 |title=Distribution of Power under Stochastic Social Choice Rules |url=https://www.jstor.org/stable/1912843 |journal=Econometrica |volume=54 |issue=4 |pages=909β921 |doi=10.2307/1912843 |issn=0012-9682 |jstor=1912843|url-access=subscription }}</ref> * Strong contraction consistency ("regularity"): probabilities cannot decrease when removing arbitrary alternatives. * Ex-post efficiency. * A probabilistic version of [[independence of irrelevant alternatives]]. Subsequent research have provided alternative proofs, as well as various extensions.<ref name=":0" />{{Rp|15}} One impossibility result relates to extending the theorem to weak preferences. It says that, with weak preferences, the properties of anonymity, SD-efficiency and SD-strategyproofness are incompatible when there are at least 4 agents and 4 alternatives.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Brandl |first1=Florian |last2=Brandt |first2=Felix |last3=Eberl |first3=Manuel |last4=Geist |first4=Christian |date=2018-01-31 |title=Proving the Incompatibility of Efficiency and Strategyproofness via SMT Solving |url=https://doi.org/10.1145/3125642 |journal=Journal of the ACM |volume=65 |issue=2 |pages=6:1β6:28 |arxiv=1604.05692 |doi=10.1145/3125642 |issn=0004-5411 |s2cid=1135734}}</ref> RD satisfies an axiom called ''population consistency'', and an axiom called ''cloning-consistency'', but violates ''composition consistency''.{{Clarify|reason=What is composition consistency?|date=July 2024}} === Computation === It is easy to implement both the RD and the RSD mechanisms in practice: just pick a random voter, or a random permutation, and let each dictator in turn pick the best option. However, sometimes one wants to compute in advance, what is the probability that a certain alternative would be chosen. With RD (when the preferences are strict), this is easy too: the probability that alternative ''x'' is chosen equals the number of voters who rank ''x'' first, divided by the total number of voters. But the situation is different with RSD (when there are indifferences): * Computing the probabilities is [[β―P|#P]]-hard;<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal |last1=Aziz |first1=Haris |last2=Brandt |first2=Felix |last3=Brill |first3=Markus |date=2013-12-01 |title=The computational complexity of random serial dictatorship |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0165176513004138 |journal=Economics Letters |language=en |volume=121 |issue=3 |pages=341β345 |arxiv=1304.3169 |doi=10.1016/j.econlet.2013.09.006 |issn=0165-1765 |s2cid=14384249}}</ref> * There is an efficient algorithm for computing the support (the alternatives chosen with a positive probability);<ref name=":1" /> * There are algorithms with tractable [[parameterized complexity]], where the parameters are: number of objects, number of alternatives, and number of voter types.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Aziz |first1=Haris |last2=Mestre |first2=JuliΓ‘n |date=2014-11-01 |title=Parametrized algorithms for random serial dictatorship |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0165489614000584 |journal=Mathematical Social Sciences |language=en |volume=72 |pages=1β6 |arxiv=1403.0974 |doi=10.1016/j.mathsocsci.2014.07.002 |issn=0165-4896 |s2cid=6719832}}</ref> * There is an exponential-time algorithm for computing the probabilities in the context of [[fractional approval voting]].<ref name=":02">{{Cite journal |last1=Bogomolnaia |first1=Anna |last2=Moulin |first2=HervΓ© |last3=Stong |first3=Richard |date=2005-06-01 |title=Collective choice under dichotomous preferences |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/abs/pii/S0022053104001322 |journal=Journal of Economic Theory |language=en |volume=122 |issue=2 |pages=165β184 |doi=10.1016/j.jet.2004.05.005 |issn=0022-0531}}</ref>{{Rp|Appendix}} ===For multimember bodies=== If the random ballot is used to select the members of a multi-constituency body, it can create a kind of [[proportional representation]] on average across elections. If the winner of each race is chosen randomly, then as the number of seats in a legislature grows, the percentage representation of each party in the elected body will get closer and closer to their actual proportion of the vote across the entire electorate. At the same time, the chance of a randomly selected highly unrepresentative body diminishes. For example, say a minority party has 1% of the vote. This party would, in a 50-person assembly, have a vanishingly small chance of winning a majority. Using the [[binomial distribution]], the probability is given by: :<math> \sum_{k=0}^{24} {50 \choose k} \left(\frac{99}{100}\right)^k\left(\frac{1}{100}\right)^{50-k} = I_{1/100}(26, 25) \approx 10^{-38} </math> ==Randomness in other electoral systems== There are various other elements of randomness (other than tie-breaking) in existing electoral systems. ===Order of listed candidates=== It is often observed that candidates who are placed in a high position on the ballot-paper will receive extra votes as a result, from voters who are apathetic (especially in elections with [[compulsory voting]]) or who have a strong preference for a party but are indifferent among individual candidates representing that party (when there are two or more). For this reason, many societies have abandoned traditional alphabetical listing of candidates on the ballot in favour of either ranking by the parties (e.g., the [[Australian Senate]]), placement by lot, or rotation (e.g. the [[Hare-Clark]] STV-PR system used in [[Tasmania]] and the [[Australian Capital Territory]]). When candidates are ordered by lot on the ballot, the advantage of [[donkey voting]] can be decisive in a close race. ===Transfer votes=== In some [[single transferable vote]] (STV) systems of [[proportional representation]], an elected candidate's surplus of votes over and above the [[Droop quota|quota]] is transferred by selecting the required number of ballot papers at random. Thus, if the quota is 1,000 votes, a candidate who polls 1,200 [[first preference]] votes has a surplus of 200 votes that s/he does not need. In some STV systems ([[Republic of Ireland|Ireland]] since 1922, and [[Australia]] from 1918 to 1984), electoral officials would select 200 ballot-papers randomly from the 1,200. However, this has been criticised since it is not replicable if a recount is required. As a result, Australia has adopted a variant of [[fractional transfer]], a.k.a. the "[[Gregory method]]", by which, in this example, all 1,200 ballot-papers are transferred but are marked down in value to 0.1666 (one-sixth) of a vote each. This means that 1,000 votes "stay with" the elected candidate, while the value of the 1,200 ballot-papers transferred equals only 200 votes. ===Selecting winners=== [[Sortition]] is a voting method which{{snd}}rather than choosing ballots{{snd}}chooses candidates directly by lot, with no input from the voters (except perhaps a [[Sortition#Methods|nominating or screening process]]). This is not the same as random ballot, since random ballot is weighted in favor of candidates who receive more votes. Random ballot would behave identically to random winner only if all candidates received the same number of votes. == See also == * [[Sortition]] * [[Dictatorship mechanism]] * [[Maximal lotteries]] ==References== {{reflist}} [[Category:Electoral systems]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Clarify
(
edit
)
Template:Electoral systems
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Rp
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:Snd
(
edit
)