Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Rational expectations
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Economics concept}} {{Macroeconomics sidebar}}'''Rational expectations''' is an economic theory that seeks to infer the [[macroeconomic]] consequences of individuals' decisions based on all available knowledge. It assumes that individuals' actions are based on the best available economic theory and information. == History == The concept of rational expectations was first introduced by [[John Muth|John F. Muth]] in his paper "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements" published in 1961. [[Robert Lucas Jr.|Robert Lucas]] and [[Thomas J. Sargent|Thomas Sargent]] further developed the theory in the 1970s and 1980s which became seminal works on the topic and were widely used in [[microeconomics]].<ref name=":0">{{Cite web |title=Rational Expectations |url=https://corporatefinanceinstitute.com/resources/economics/rational-expectations/ |access-date=2023-04-25 |website=Corporate Finance Institute |language=en-US}}</ref> '''Significant Findings''' [[John Muth|Muth’s]] work introduces the concept of rational expectations and discusses its implications for economic theory. He argues that individuals are rational and use all available information to make unbiased, informed predictions about the future. This means that individuals do not make systematic errors in their predictions and that their predictions are not biased by past errors. Muth’s paper also discusses the implication of rational expectations for economic theory. One key implication is that government policies, such as changes in monetary or fiscal policy, may not be as effective if individuals’ expectations are not considered. For example, if individuals expect inflation to increase, they may anticipate that the central bank will raise interest rates to combat inflation, which could lead to higher borrowing costs and slower economic growth. Similarly, if individuals expect a recession, they may reduce their spending and investment, which could lead to a [[Self-fulfilling prophecy|self-fulfilling prophecy]].<ref>{{Cite web |last=Muth |first=John.F |date=1961 |title=Rational expectations and the theory of price movements |url=https://citeseerx.ist.psu.edu/document?repid=rep1&type=pdf&doi=948a6261d8fc75496416ddf463fdb46cd171da32}}</ref> [[Robert Lucas Jr.|Lucas]]’ paper “Expectations and the Neutrality of Money” expands on Muth's work and sheds light on the relationship between rational expectations and monetary policy. The paper argues that when individuals hold rational expectations, changes in the money supply do not have real effects on the economy and the neutrality of money holds. Lucas presents a theoretical model that incorporates rational expectations into an analysis of the effects of changes in the money supply. The model suggests that individuals adjust their expectations in response to changes in the money supply, which eliminates the effect on real variables such as output and employment. He argues that a stable monetary policy that is consistent with individuals' rational expectations will be more effective in promoting economic stability than attempts to manipulate the money supply.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Lucas |first=R.E |date=1970 |title=Expectations and the Neutrality of Money |url=http://www.economia.unam.mx/biblioteca/Pdf/T-III-BG-%20Expectations%20and%20the%20Neutrality.pdf}}</ref> In 1973, [[Thomas J. Sargent|Thomas J Sargent]] published the article “Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemployment”, which was an important contribution to the development and application of the concept of rational expectations in economic theory and policy. By assuming individuals are forward-looking and rational, Sargent argues that rational expectations can help explain fluctuations in key economic variables such as the real interest rate and the natural rate of employment. He also suggests that the concept of the natural rate of unemployment can be used to help policymakers set macroeconomic policy. This concept suggests that there is a trade-off between unemployment and inflation in the short run, but in the long run, the economy will return to the natural rate of unemployment, which is determined by structural factors such as the skills of the labour force and the efficiency of the labour market. Sargent argues that policymakers should take this concept into account when setting macroeconomic policy, as policies that try to push unemployment below the natural rate will only lead to higher inflation in the long run.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Sargent |first=T.J |date=1973 |title=Rational Expectations, the Real Rate of Interest, and the Natural Rate of Unemployment |url=https://www.brookings.edu/wp-content/uploads/1973/06/1973b_bpea_sargent_fand_goldfeld.pdf}}</ref> ==Theory== The key idea of rational expectations is that individuals make decisions based on all available information, including their own expectations about future events. This implies that individuals are rational and use all available information to make decisions. Another important idea is that individuals adjust their expectations in response to new information. In this way, individuals are assumed to be forward-looking and able to adapt to changing circumstances. They will learn from past trends and experiences to make their best guess of the future.<ref name=":0" /> It is assumed that an individual's predicted outcome do not differ systematically from the market [[economic equilibrium|equilibrium]] given that they do not make systematic errors when predicting the future. In an economic model, this is typically modelled by assuming that the expected value of a variable is equal to the expected value predicted by the model. For example, suppose that ''P'' is the equilibrium price in a simple market, determined by [[supply and demand]]. The theory of rational expectations implies that the actual price will only deviate from the expectation if there is an 'information shock' caused by information unforeseeable at the time expectations were formed. In other words, ''[[ex ante]]'' the price is anticipated to equal its rational expectation: ::<math>P=P^*+\epsilon</math> :: ::<math>E[P]=P^*</math> where <math>P^*</math> is the rational expectation and <math>\epsilon</math> is the random error term, which has an expected value of zero, and is independent of <math>P^*</math>. == Mathematical derivation == If rational expectations are applied to the Phillips curve analysis, the distinction between long and short term will be completely negated, that is, there is no Phillips curve, and there is no substitute relationship between inflation rate and unemployment rate that can be utilized. The mathematical derivation is as follows: Rational expectation is consistent with objective mathematical expectation: <math>E\dot{P}_t=\dot{P}_t+\varepsilon_t</math> '''Mathematical derivation (1)''' We denote unemployment rate by <math>u_t</math>. Assuming that the actual process is known, the rate of inflation (<math>\dot P_t</math>) depends on previous monetary changes (<math>\dot M_{t-1}</math>) and changes in short-term variables such as X (for example, oil prices): (1) <math>\dot{P}=q\dot M_{t-1}+z\dot{X}_{t-1}+\varepsilon_t</math> Taking expected values, (2) <math>E\dot{P}_t=q\dot M_{t-1}+z\dot X_{t-1}</math> On the other hand, inflation rate is related to unemployment by the Phillips curve: (3) <math>\dot{P}_t=\alpha-\beta u_t+\gamma E_{t-1}(\dot{P}_t)</math> , <math>\gamma=1</math> Equating (1) and (3): (4) <math>\alpha-\beta u_t+q\dot M_{t-1}+z\dot X_{t-1}=q\dot M_{t-1}+z\dot{X}_{t-1}+\varepsilon_t</math> Cancelling terms and rearrangement gives (5) <math>u_t=\frac{\alpha-\varepsilon_t}{\beta}</math> Thus, even in the short run, there is no substitute relationship between inflation and unemployment. Random shocks, which are completely unpredictable, are the only reason why the unemployment rate deviates from the natural rate. '''Mathematical derivation (2)''' Even if the actual rate of inflation is dependent on current monetary changes, the public can make rational expectations as long as they know how monetary policy is being decided: (1) <math>\dot{P}_t=q\dot{M}_t+z\dot{X}_{t-1}+\varepsilon_t</math> Denote the change due to monetary policy by <math>\mu_t</math>. (2) <math>\dot{M}_t=g\dot{M}_{t-1}+\mu_t</math> We then substitute (2) into (1): (3) <math>\dot{P}_t=qg\dot{M}_{t-1}+z\dot{X}_{t-1}+q\mu_t+\varepsilon_{t}</math> Taking expected value at time <math>t-1</math>, (4) <math>E_{t-1}\dot{P}=qg\dot{M}_{t-1}+z\dot{X}_{t-1}</math> Using the Phillips curve relation, cancelling terms on both sides and rearrangement gives (5) <math>u_t=\frac{\alpha-q\mu_t-\varepsilon_t}{\beta}</math> The conclusion is essentially the same: random shocks that are completely unpredictable are the only thing that can cause the unemployment rate to deviate from the natural rate. ==Implications== Rational expectations theories were developed in response to perceived flaws in theories based on [[adaptive expectations]]. Under adaptive expectations, expectations of the future value of an economic variable are based on past values. For example, it assumes that individuals predict inflation by looking at historical inflation data. Under adaptive expectations, if the economy suffers from a prolonged period of rising inflation, people are assumed to always underestimate inflation. Many economists suggested that it was an unrealistic and irrational assumption, as they believe that rational individuals will learn from past experiences and trends and adjust their predictions accordingly. The rational expectations hypothesis has been used to support conclusions about economic policymaking. An example is the [[policy ineffectiveness proposition]] developed by [[Thomas Sargent]] and [[Neil Wallace]]. If the Federal Reserve attempts to lower unemployment through expansionary [[monetary policy]], economic agents will anticipate the effects of the change of policy and raise their expectations of future inflation accordingly. This will counteract the expansionary effect of the increased money supply, suggesting that the government can only increase the inflation rate but not employment. If agents do not form rational expectations or if prices are not completely flexible, discretional and completely anticipated, economic policy actions can trigger real changes.<ref>{{cite book |last=Galbács |first=Peter |title=The Theory of New Classical Macroeconomics. A Positive Critique |location=Heidelberg/New York/Dordrecht/London |publisher=Springer |year=2015 |isbn= 978-3-319-17578-2 |doi=10.1007/978-3-319-17578-2 |series=Contributions to Economics }}</ref> == Criticism == While the rational expectations theory has been widely influential in macroeconomic analysis, it has also been subject to criticism: '''Unrealistic assumptions''': The theory implies that individuals are in a fixed point, where their expectations about aggregate economic variables on average are correct. This is unlikely to be the case, due to limited information available and human error.<ref name=":1">{{Cite journal |last=Mankiw |first=N.G |date=2006 |title=The Macroeconomist as Scientist and Engineer |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=20 |issue=4 |pages=29–46 |doi=10.1257/jep.20.4.29 |url=https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdf/10.1257%2Fjep.20.4.29}}</ref> '''Limited empirical support''': While there is some evidence that individuals do incorporate expectations into their decision-making, it is unclear whether they do so in the way predicted by the rational expectations theory.<ref name=":1" /> '''Misspecification of models''': The rational expectations theory assumes that individuals have a common understanding of the model used to make predictions. However, if the model is misspecified, this can lead to incorrect predictions.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Romer |first=David |date=2000 |title=Keynesian Macroeconomics without the LM Curve |journal=Journal of Economic Perspectives |volume=14 |issue=2 |pages=149–170 |doi=10.1257/jep.14.2.149 |url=https://pubs.aeaweb.org/doi/pdf/10.1257/jep.14.2.149}}</ref> '''Inability to explain certain phenomena:''' The theory is also criticized for its inability to explain certain phenomena, such as 'irrational' bubbles and crashes in financial markets.<ref>{{Cite web |last=Shiller |first=R.J |date=1980 |title=Do stock prices move too much to be justified by subsequent changes in dividends? |url=https://www.nber.org/system/files/working_papers/w0456/w0456.pdf}}</ref> '''Lack of attention to distributional effects:''' Critics argue that the rational expectations theory focuses too much on aggregate outcomes and does not pay enough attention to the distributional effects of economic policies.<ref name=":1" /> == See also == {{div col|colwidth=22em}} * [[Adaptive expectations]] * [[Behavioral economics]] * [[Dynamic stochastic general equilibrium]] * [[Factors of production]] * [[Game theory]] * [[Homo economicus]] * [[Market price]] * [[Lucas aggregate supply function]] * [[Lucas critique]] * [[Lucas island model]] * [[Optimism]] * [[Optimism bias]] * [[Perfectionism (psychology)|Perfectionism]] * [[Rationality]] * [[Peter principle|The Peter principle]]{{div col end}} ==Notes== {{Reflist}} == References == * Hanish C. Lodhia (2005) "The Irrationality of Rational Expectations – An Exploration into Economic Fallacy". 1st Edition, Warwick University Press, UK. * [[Maarten Janssen|Maarten C. W. Janssen]] (1993) "Microfoundations: A Critical Inquiry". Routledge. * [[John Muth|John F. Muth]] (1961) "Rational Expectations and the Theory of Price Movements" reprinted in ''The new classical macroeconomics. Volume 1.'' (1992): 3–23 (International Library of Critical Writings in Economics, vol. 19. Aldershot, UK: Elgar.) * [[Thomas J. Sargent]] (1987). "Rational expectations," ''[[The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics]]'', v. 4, pp. 76–79. * N.E. Savin (1987). "Rational expectations: econometric implications," ''[[The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics]]'', v. 4, pp. 79–85. == External links == {{wikiquote}} * {{cite encyclopedia |last1=Sargent |first1=Thomas J. |author-link1= Thomas Sargent |editor= David R. Henderson |editor-link= David R. Henderson |encyclopedia=[[Concise Encyclopedia of Economics]] |title=Rational Expectations |url=http://www.econlib.org/library/Enc/RationalExpectations.html |year=2008 |edition= 2nd |publisher=[[Library of Economics and Liberty]] |location=Indianapolis |isbn=978-0865976658 |oclc=237794267}} {{Economics}} {{Schools of economic thought}} {{Authority control}} [[Category:New classical macroeconomics]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Authority control
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite encyclopedia
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Div col
(
edit
)
Template:Div col end
(
edit
)
Template:Economics
(
edit
)
Template:Macroeconomics sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Schools of economic thought
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:Sister project
(
edit
)
Template:Wikiquote
(
edit
)