Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Real and nominal value
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Value in economics and accounting}} {{Economics sidebar}} In [[economics]], '''nominal''' '''value''' refers to value measured in terms of absolute [[money]] amounts, whereas '''real value''' is considered and measured against the actual [[goods or services]] for which it can be exchanged at a given time. Real value takes into account inflation and the [[Value (economics)|value]] of an asset in relation to its [[purchasing power]]. In macroeconomics, the [[real gross domestic product]] compensates for inflation so economists can exclude inflation from growth figures, and see how much an economy actually grows. Nominal GDP would include inflation, and thus be higher. ==Commodity bundles, price indices and inflation== A '''commodity bundle''' is a sample of [[good (economics)|goods]], which is used to represent the sum total of goods across the economy to which the goods belong, for the purpose of comparison across different times (or locations). At a single point of time, a commodity bundle consists of a list of goods, and each good in the list has a market price and a quantity. The market value of the good is the market price times the quantity at that point of time. The '''nominal''' value of the commodity bundle at a point of time is the total market value of the commodity bundle, depending on the market price, and the quantity, of each good in the commodity bundle which are current at the time. A [[price index]] is the relative price of a commodity bundle. A price index can be measured over time, or at different locations or markets. If it is measured over time, it is a series of values <math>P_t</math> over time <math>t</math>. A [[time series]] price index is calculated relative to a '''base''' or '''reference''' date. <math>P_0</math> is the value of the index at the base date. For example, if the base date is (the end of) 1992, <math>P_0</math> is the value of the index at (the end of) 1992. The price index is typically '''normalized''' to start at 100 at the base date, so <math>P_0</math> is set to 100. The length of time between each value of <math>t</math> and the next one, is normally constant regular time interval, such as a calendar year. <math>P_t</math> is the value of the price index at time <math>t</math> after the base date. <math>P_t</math> equals 100 times the value of the commodity bundle at time <math>t</math>, divided by the value of the commodity bundle at the base date. If the price of the commodity bundle has increased by one percent over the first period after the base date, then ''P''<sub>1</sub> = 101. The '''inflation rate''' <math>i_t</math> between time <math>t-1</math> and time <math>t</math> is the change in the price index divided by the price index value at time <math>t-1</math>: <math>i_t = \frac{P_t-P_{t-1}}{P_{t-1}}</math> :<math>= \frac{P_t}{P_{t-1}} - 1</math> expressed as a percentage. ==Real value== The nominal value of a commodity bundle tends to change over time. In contrast, by definition, the '''real value''' of the commodity bundle in aggregate remains the same over time. The real values of individual goods or commodities may rise or fall against each other, in relative terms, but a representative commodity bundle as a whole retains its real value as a constant from one period to the next. Real values can for example be expressed in [[constant dollars|constant 1992 dollars]], with the price level fixed 100 at the base date. [[File:U.S. Real and Nominal Gas Prices 1996 to 2016 - v1.png|thumb|400px|Comparison of real and nominal gas prices 1996 to 2016, illustrating the formula for conversion. Here the base year is 2016.]] The price index is applied to adjust the nominal value <math>Q</math> of a quantity, such as wages or total production, to obtain its real value. The real value is the value expressed in terms of [[purchasing power]] in the base year. The index price divided by its base-year value <math>P_t / P_0</math> gives the growth factor of the price index. Real values can be found by dividing the nominal value by the growth factor of a price index. Using the price index growth factor as a divisor for converting a nominal value into a real value, the real value at time ''t'' relative to the base date is: :<math>\frac{P_0 \cdot Q_t}{P_t}</math> ==Real growth rate== The real growth rate <math>r_t</math> is the change in a nominal quantity <math>Q_t</math> in real terms since the previous date <math>t-1</math>. It measures by how much the buying power of the quantity has changed over a single period. :<math>r_t = \frac{P_0 \cdot Q_t}{P_t} \Bigg/ \frac{P_0 \cdot Q_{t-1}}{P_{t-1}} - 1</math> ::<math>= \frac{P_{t-1} \cdot Q_t}{P_t \cdot Q_{t-1}} - 1</math> ::<math>= \frac{Q_t}{Q_{t-1}} (\frac{P_t}{P_{t-1}})^{-1} - 1</math> ::<math>= \frac{1 + g_t}{1 + i_t} - 1</math> where <math>g_t</math> is the nominal growth rate of <math>Q_t</math>, and <math>i_t</math> is the inflation rate. :<math>1 + r_t = \frac{1 + g_t}{1 + i_t}</math> For values of <math>i_t</math> between β1 and 1 (i.e. Β±100 percent), we have the [[Taylor series]] :<math>(1 + i_t)^{-1} = 1 - i_t + i_t^2 - i_t^3 + ...</math> so :<math>1 + r_t = (1 + g_t)(1 - i_t + i_t^2 - i_t^3 + ...)</math> :::<math>= 1 + g_t - i_t - g_t i_t + i_t^2 + \text {higher order terms.}</math> Hence as a first-order (''i.e.'' linear) approximation, :<math>r_t = g_t - i_t</math> ==Real wages and real gross domestic products== The bundle of goods used to measure the [[Consumer Price Index]] (CPI) is applicable to consumers. So for wage earners as consumers, an appropriate way to measure real wages (the buying power of wages) is to divide the nominal wage (after-tax) by the growth factor in the CPI. [[Gross domestic product]] (GDP) is a measure of aggregate output. Nominal GDP in a particular period reflects prices that were current at the time, whereas real GDP compensates for inflation. Price indices and the U.S. [[National Income and Product Accounts]] are constructed from bundles of commodities and their respective prices. In the case of GDP, a suitable price index is the [http://bea.gov/bea/glossary/glossary.cfm?key_word=GDP_price_index&letter=G#GDP_price_index GDP price index.] In the U.S. National Income and Product Accounts, nominal GDP is called ''GDP in current dollars'' (that is, in prices current for each designated year), and real GDP is called ''GDP in [base-year] dollars'' (that is, in dollars that can [[GDP deflator#Calculation|purchase]] the same quantity of commodities as in the base year). ==Example== {|style="border:1px solid #999; text-align:leftcenter; margin: auto;" cellspacing="20" |If for years 1 and 2 (possibly a span of 20 years apart), the nominal wage and price level ''P'' of goods are respectively :nominal wage rate: $10 in year 1 and $16 in year 2 :price level: 1.00 in year 1 and 1.333 in year 2, then real wages using year 1 as the base year are respectively: :$10 (= $10/1.00) in year 1 and $12 (= $16/1.333) in year 2. The real wage each year measures the buying power of the hourly wage in common terms. In this example, the real wage rate increased by 20 percent, meaning that an hour's wage would buy 20% more goods in year 2 compared with year 1. |} ==Real interest rates== {{Main|Real interest rate}} As was shown in the section above on the real growth rate, :<math>1 + r_t = \frac{1 + g_t}{1 + i_t}</math> where :<math>r_t</math> is the rate of increase of a quantity in real terms, :<math>g_t</math> is the rate of increase of the same quantity in nominal terms, and :<math>i_t</math> is the rate of inflation, and as a first-order approximation, :<math>r_t = g_t - i_t.</math> In the case where the growing quantity is a [[financial asset]], <math>g_t</math> is a [[nominal interest rate]] and <math>r_t</math> is the corresponding [[real interest rate]]; the first-order approximation <math>r_t = g_t - i_t</math> is known as the [[Fisher equation]].<ref>{{cite book | last=Benninga | first=Simon |author2=Oded Sarig | year=1997 | title=''Corporate Finance: A Valuation Approach'' | publisher=[[The McGraw-Hill Companies]] | pages=[https://archive.org/details/corporatefinance00benn/page/21 21] | isbn=0-07-005099-6 |url=https://archive.org/details/corporatefinance00benn | url-access=registration }}</ref> Looking back into the past, the [[Ex post#ex post|''ex post'']] real interest rate is approximately the historical nominal interest rate minus inflation. Looking forward into the future, the expected real interest rate is approximately the nominal interest rate minus the expected inflation rate. ==Cross-sectional comparison== Not only [[time-series]] data, as above, but also [[cross-sectional data]] which depends on prices which may vary geographically for example, can be adjusted in a similar way. For example, the total value of a good produced in a region of a country depends on both the amount and the price. To compare the output of different regions, the nominal output in a region can be adjusted by repricing the goods at common or average prices. ==See also== {{cols|colwidth=16em}} *[[Aggregation problem]] *[[Classical dichotomy]] *[[Constant Item Purchasing Power Accounting]] *[[Cost-of-living index]] *[[Deflation]] *[[Financial repression]] *[[Fisher equation]] *[[Index (economics)]] *[[Inflation]] *[[Inflation accounting]] *[[Inflation hedge]] *[[Interest]] *[[Money illusion]] *[[National accounts]] *[[Neutrality of money]] *[[NumΓ©raire]] *[[Real interest rate]] *[[Real prices and ideal prices]] *[[Template:Inflation]] β for price conversions in Wikipedia articles {{colend}} ==References== {{reflist}} ==Bibliography== *{{cite book |first=W. E. |last=Diewert |author-link=Walter Erwin Diewert |chapter=Index Numbers |orig-year=1987 |year=2008 |title=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |pages=1β32 |edition=2nd |doi=10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_940-2 |title-link=The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics |isbn=978-1-349-95121-5 }} *{{cite book |first=R. |last=O'Donnell |year=1987 |chapter=Real and Nominal Quantities |title=The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics |volume=v. 4 |pages=97β98 }} ([[The Wealth of Nations|Adam Smith]]'s early distinction vindicated) *{{cite journal |first=Amartya |last=Sen |author-link=Amartya Sen |year=1979 |title=The Welfare Basis of Real Income Comparisons: A Survey |journal=[[Journal of Economic Literature]] |volume=17 |issue=1 |pages=1β45 |jstor=2723639 }} *{{cite book |first=D. |last=Usher |year=1987 |chapter=Real Income |title=The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics |volume=v. 4 |pages=104β05 }} ==External links== *[http://www.dallasfed.org/research/basics/nominal.cfm DataBasics: Deflating Nominal Values to Real Values] from [[Federal Reserve Bank of Dallas]] *[http://data.bls.gov/cgi-bin/cpicalc.pl CPI Inflation Calculator] from U.S. [[Bureau of Labor Statistics]] {{economics}} {{United States β Commonwealth of Nations recessions}} [[Category:Inflation]] [[Category:Valuation (finance)]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Colend
(
edit
)
Template:Cols
(
edit
)
Template:Economics
(
edit
)
Template:Economics sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Main
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)
Template:United States β Commonwealth of Nations recessions
(
edit
)