Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Subjective theory of value
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Economic theory proposed by Austrian scholar Carl Menger}} {{austrian School sidebar|theory}} The '''subjective theory of value (STV)''' is an [[theory of value (economics)|economic theory]] for explaining how the value of goods and services are not only set but also how they can fluctuate over time. The contrasting system is typically known as the [[labor theory of value]]. STV's development helped to better understand human action and decision making in economics. The theory claims that the [[value (economics)|value]] of a good is not determined by any inherent property of the good, nor by the cumulative value of components or labor needed to produce it, but instead is determined by the individuals or entities who are buying (and/or selling) that good.<ref>Menger, C. ''Principles of Economics''. [https://www.mises.org/sites/default/files/Principles%20of%20Economics_5.pdf p. 120]</ref> Thus a good's value may increase substantially following its creation if the good is perceived as being of greater importance, or as being more desirable than before. There are many variables that can influence this process, including, but not limited to, changes in the age of the good, personal affinity, cultural significance, scarcity, as well as situational circumstances. This is often seen in the case of [[collectable]] items such as cars, vinyl records, and comic books. An additional variable, as Austrian economist [[Carl Menger]] pointed out, is the estimation of a good's value due to uncertainty and lack of knowledge, in which people "sometimes estimate the importance of various satisfactions in a manner contrary to their real importance".<ref>Menger, C. ''Principles of Economics''. [https://www.mises.org/sites/default/files/Principles%20of%20Economics_5.pdf p. 148]</ref> It is one of several theories that sprang from the [[Marginal Revolution (disambiguation)|marginal revolution]], which was a departure from classical economics, and in particular STV departed from the [[labor theory of value]]. The modern version of the subjective theory of value was created independently and nearly simultaneously by [[William Stanley Jevons]], [[LΓ©on Walras]], and [[Carl Menger]] in the late 19th century.<ref name="stigler">Stigler, George (1950) "The Development of Utility Theory. I" ''The Journal of Political Economy''</ref> The theory has helped explain why the value of non-essential goods can be higher than essential ones, and how relatively expensive goods can have relatively low production costs.<ref>Menger, C. ''Principles of Economics''. [https://www.mises.org/sites/default/files/Principles%20of%20Economics_5.pdf p. 140]</ref> ==Overview== According to the subjective theory of value, by assuming that all [[trade]]s between individuals are voluntary, it can be concluded that both parties to the trade subjectively perceive the goods, labour or money they receive, as being of higher value to the goods, labour or money they give away. The theory holds that one can create value simply by trading with someone who values the items higher, without necessarily modifying them. Wealth is understood to refer to individuals' subjective valuation of their possessions, and voluntary trades may increase the total wealth in society.<ref>[http://www.huffingtonpost.com/steve-mariotti/subjective-versus-objecti_b_880274.html Steve Mariotti, "Subjective Versus Objective Costs: How the Labor Theory of Value Almost Destroyed the World"] 06/20/2011</ref> This is because each participant of the voluntary transaction has gained more value than they originally had. This suggests that items cannot be objectively valued as any value placed upon the item is only correct if both buyer and seller agree on the price and a transaction takes place. A seller may value an item in their possession higher than any buyer will value it leading to either a price reduction until the item's price equals a buyer's value of the item, or the seller will continue to value the item higher than any buyer and no transaction will occur. Individuals will experience more radical improvements to life and satisfaction from acquiring the first unit of a good compared to the [[marginal utility]] from acquiring additional units of a good. They will initially prioritise obtaining the goods they most need (of central, not marginal utility), such as essential food, but once their need for it is satisfied up to a certain level, their desire for other luxury or surplus goods will begin to rise, and the satisfaction obtained from the original essential goods will diminish.<ref name="menger2">Menger, C. ''Principles of Economics''. [https://www.mises.org/sites/default/files/Principles%20of%20Economics_5.pdf p. 127]</ref> Proponents of the theory also believe that in a [[free market]], [[competition]] between individuals seeking to trade goods they possess and services they can provide for goods they perceive as being of higher value to them results in a [[market equilibrium]] set of prices emerging. This occurs during auctions. Bidders are able to express their belief in the value of each item via bids. As each person raises their bid, the value of the item rises even though the nature and function of the item has not changed. This behaviour can lead to the [[winner's curse]]. == Labour theory of value == {{main|Labour theory of value}} [[Classical economists]] such as [[David Ricardo]] proposed a labour theory of value that states there is a direct correlation between the value of a good and the labour required to produce the good, concluding "The value of a commodity, or the quantity of any other commodity for which it will exchange, depends on the relative quantity of labour which is necessary for its production, and not on the greater or less compensation which is paid for that labour."<ref>{{Cite web|title=On The Principles of Political Economy and Taxation |first=David |last=Ricardo |year=1817 |url=https://www.marxists.org/reference/subject/economics/ricardo/tax/ch01.htm|access-date=2020-08-19|website=www.marxists.org}}</ref> Ricardo clarified that this correlation did not effectively connect those with market prices, or 'value in exchange', seeing them as separately derived from the quantity of labour input and other production factors.<ref name="stigler" /> Increasing wages would not necessarily cause price rises, but conversely price rises may not cause wages to increase. Carl Menger argued that production was simply another case of the theory of marginal utility,<ref name="stigler" /> and that labourers' wage-earning potential is set by the value of their work to others rather than subsistence costs, and they work because they value remuneration more highly than inactivity.<ref name="menger">Menger, C. ''Principles of Economics''. [https://www.mises.org/sites/default/files/Principles%20of%20Economics_5.pdf pp. 169β173]</ref> A combination of both labour and subjective theories can be seen in the formulations of English economist [[Alfred Marshall]]. He argued that prices are determined by both the objective costs of production, the supply, and the subjective utility of consumers, the demand. This approach is in line with the modern conception of how market prices are determined, where both the demand and supply curves intersect.<ref>Stringham, P. Green. [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1676261 "Economic Value and Cost are Subjective"], 2010, p. 5-6.</ref> This is in contrast to other 19th century theories which view costs through a type of subjective value lens. Since the subjective value holds that buyers use their own value judgements, the same goes for sellers, and thus the mechanism of production. Austrian economist [[Ludwig von Mises]] believes that production costs are determined by a seller's evaluations of their [[opportunity cost]]s, or the sellers "marginal utility lost of having fewer of that good".<ref>Stringham, P. Green. [https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1676261 "Economic Value and Cost are Subjective"], 2010, p. 6.</ref> Under this, supply curves are also set by subjective preferences. ==See also== * [[Advertising]] * [[Behavioral economics]] * [[Consumer capitalism]] * [[Distribution of wealth]] * [[Expected utility hypothesis]] * [[Intrinsic theory of value]] * [[Labour theory of value]] * [[Marginalism]] * [[Marketing]] * [[Objectivism]] * [[Peer pressure]] * [[Power theory of value]] * [[Religious values]] * [[Social comparison theory]] * [[Use value]] * [[Value (ethics and social sciences)]] * [[Value theory]] ==References== {{reflist}} {{Portal bar|Business and economics|Libertarianism}} {{DEFAULTSORT:Subjective Theory Of Value}} [[Category:Theory of value (economics)]] [[Category:Subjectivism]] [[Category:Utility]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Austrian School sidebar
(
edit
)
Template:Cite web
(
edit
)
Template:Main
(
edit
)
Template:Portal bar
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)