Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Supermodular function
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
{{Short description|Class of mathematical functions}} In mathematics, a '''supermodular function''' is a function on a [[Lattice (order)|lattice]] that, informally, has the property of being characterized by "increasing differences." Seen from the point of [[Set function|set functions]], this can also be viewed as a relationship of "increasing returns", where adding more elements to a subset increases its valuation. In [[economics]], supermodular functions are often used as a formal expression of complementarity in preferences among goods. Supermodular functions are studied and have applications in [[game theory]], [[economics]], [[Lattice (order)|lattice theory]], [[combinatorial optimization]], and [[machine learning]]. == Definition == Let <math>(X, \preceq)</math> be a [[Lattice (order)|lattice]]. A real-valued function <math>f: X \rightarrow \mathbb{R}</math> is called '''supermodular''' if <math>f(x \vee y) + f(x \wedge y) \geq f(x) + f(y)</math> for all <math>x, y \in X</math>.<ref>{{Cite book |title=Supermodularity and complementarity |date=1998 |publisher=Princeton University Press |isbn=978-0-691-03244-3 |editor-last=Topkis |editor-first=Donald M. |series=Frontiers of economic research |location=Princeton, N.J}}</ref> If the inequality is strict, then <math>f</math> is '''strictly supermodular''' on <math>X</math>. If <math>-f</math> is (strictly) supermodular then ''f'' is called ('''strictly) submodular'''. A function that is both submodular and supermodular is called '''modular'''. This corresponds to the inequality being changed to an equality. We can also define supermodular functions where the underlying lattice is the vector space <math>\mathbb{R}^n</math>. Then the function <math>f : \mathbb{R}^n \to \mathbb{R}</math> is '''supermodular''' if <math> f(x \uparrow y) + f(x \downarrow y) \geq f(x) + f(y) </math> for all <math>x</math>, <math>y \isin \mathbb{R}^{n}</math>, where <math>x \uparrow y</math> denotes the componentwise maximum and <math>x \downarrow y</math> the componentwise minimum of <math>x</math> and <math>y</math>. If ''f'' is twice continuously differentiable, then supermodularity is equivalent to the condition<ref>The equivalence between the definition of supermodularity and its calculus formulation is sometimes called [[Topkis's theorem|Topkis' characterization theorem]]. See {{cite journal |first1=Paul |last1=Milgrom |first2=John |last2=Roberts |year=1990 |title=Rationalizability, Learning, and Equilibrium in Games with Strategic Complementarities |journal=[[Econometrica]] |volume=58 |issue=6 |pages=1255β1277 [p. 1261] |jstor=2938316 |doi=10.2307/2938316 }}</ref> :<math> \frac{\partial ^2 f}{\partial z_i\, \partial z_j} \geq 0 \mbox{ for all } i \neq j.</math> ==Supermodularity in economics and game theory== The concept of supermodularity is used in the social sciences to analyze how one [[Agent (economics)|agent's]] decision affects the incentives of others. Consider a [[symmetric game]] with a smooth payoff function <math>\,f</math> defined over actions <math>\,z_i</math> of two or more players <math>i \in {1,2,\dots,N}</math>. Suppose the action space is continuous; for simplicity, suppose each action is chosen from an interval: <math>z_i \in [a,b]</math>. In this context, supermodularity of <math>\,f</math> implies that an increase in player <math>\,i</math>'s choice <math>\,z_i</math> increases the marginal payoff <math>df/dz_j</math> of action <math>\,z_j</math> for all other players <math>\,j</math>. That is, if any player <math>\,i</math> chooses a higher <math>\,z_i</math>, all other players <math>\,j</math> have an incentive to raise their choices <math>\,z_j</math> too. Following the terminology of Bulow, [[John Geanakoplos|Geanakoplos]], and [[Paul Klemperer|Klemperer]] (1985), economists call this situation [[strategic complements|strategic complementarity]], because players' strategies are complements to each other.<ref>{{cite journal |first1=Jeremy I. |last1=Bulow |first2=John D. |last2=Geanakoplos |first3=Paul D. |last3=Klemperer |year=1985 |title=Multimarket Oligopoly: Strategic Substitutes and Complements |journal=[[Journal of Political Economy]] |volume=93 |issue=3 |pages=488β511 |doi=10.1086/261312 |citeseerx=10.1.1.541.2368 |s2cid=154872708 }}</ref> This is the basic property underlying examples of [[General equilibrium#Uniqueness|multiple equilibria]] in [[coordination game]]s.<ref>{{cite journal |first1=Russell |last1=Cooper |first2=Andrew |last2=John |year=1988 |title=Coordinating coordination failures in Keynesian models |journal=[[Quarterly Journal of Economics]] |volume=103 |issue=3 |pages=441β463 |doi=10.2307/1885539 |jstor=1885539 |url=http://cowles.yale.edu/sites/default/files/files/pub/d07/d0745-r.pdf }}</ref> The opposite case of supermodularity of <math>\,f</math>, called submodularity, corresponds to the situation of [[strategic complements|strategic substitutability]]. An increase in <math>\,z_i</math> lowers the marginal payoff to all other player's choices <math>\,z_j</math>, so strategies are substitutes. That is, if <math>\,i</math> chooses a higher <math>\,z_i</math>, other players have an incentive to pick a ''lower'' <math>\,z_j</math>. For example, Bulow et al. consider the interactions of many [[Imperfect competition|imperfectly competitive]] firms. When an increase in output by one firm raises the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic complements. When an increase in output by one firm lowers the marginal revenues of the other firms, production decisions are strategic substitutes. A supermodular [[utility function]] is often related to [[complementary goods]]. However, this view is disputed.<ref>{{Cite journal|doi=10.1016/j.jet.2008.06.004 |title=Supermodularity and preferences |journal=[[Journal of Economic Theory]] |volume=144 |issue=3 |pages=1004 |year=2009 |last1=Chambers |first1=Christopher P. |last2=Echenique |first2=Federico |citeseerx=10.1.1.122.6861 }}</ref> ==Supermodular set functions== Supermodularity can also be defined for [[Set function|set functions]], which are functions defined over subsets of a larger set. Many properties of [[Submodular set function|submodular set functions]] can be rephrased to apply to supermodular set functions. Intuitively, a supermodular function over a set of subsets demonstrates "increasing returns". This means that if each subset is assigned a real number that corresponds to its value, the value of a subset will always be less than the value of a larger subset which contains it. Alternatively, this means that as we add elements to a set, we increase its value. === Definition === Let <math>S</math> be a finite set. A set function <math>f: 2^S \to \mathbb{R}</math> is '''supermodular''' if it satifies the following (equivalent) conditions:<ref>{{Citation |last=McCormick |first=S. Thomas |title=Discrete Optimization |chapter=Submodular Function Minimization |date=2005 |series=Handbooks in Operations Research and Management Science |volume=12 |pages=321β391 |chapter-url=https://linkinghub.elsevier.com/retrieve/pii/S0927050705120076 |access-date=2024-12-12 |publisher=Elsevier |language=en |doi=10.1016/s0927-0507(05)12007-6 |isbn=978-0-444-51507-0}}</ref> # <math> f(A)+f(B) \leq f(A \cap B) + f(A \cup B) </math> for all <math> A, B \subseteq S </math>. # <math> f(A \cup \{v\}) - f(A) \leq f(B \cup \{v\}) - f(B) </math> for all <math> A \subset B \subset V </math>, where <math> v \notin B </math>. A set function <math>f</math> is submodular if <math>-f</math> is supermodular, and modular if it is both supermodular and submodular. === Additional Facts === * If <math> f </math> is modular and <math> g </math> is submodular, then <math> f-g </math> is a supermodular function. * A non-negative supermodular function is also a superadditive function. == Optimization Techniques == There are specialized techniques for optimizing submodular functions. Theory and enumeration algorithms for finding local and global maxima (minima) of submodular (supermodular) functions can be found in "Maximization of submodular functions: Theory and enumeration algorithms", B. Goldengorin.<ref>{{Cite journal |last=Goldengorin |first=Boris |date=2009-10-01 |title=Maximization of submodular functions: Theory and enumeration algorithms |url=https://www.sciencedirect.com/science/article/pii/S0377221708007418 |journal=European Journal of Operational Research |language=en |volume=198 |issue=1 |pages=102β112 |doi=10.1016/j.ejor.2008.08.022 |issn=0377-2217|url-access=subscription }}</ref> ==See also== * [[Pseudo-Boolean function]] * [[Topkis's theorem]] * [[Submodular set function]] * [[Superadditive]] * [[Utility functions on indivisible goods]] ==Notes and references== {{Reflist}} {{DEFAULTSORT:Supermodular Function}} [[Category:Order theory]] [[Category:Optimization of ordered sets]] [[Category:Generalized convexity]] [[Category:Supermodular functions]]
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)
Pages transcluded onto the current version of this page
(
help
)
:
Template:Citation
(
edit
)
Template:Cite book
(
edit
)
Template:Cite journal
(
edit
)
Template:Reflist
(
edit
)
Template:Short description
(
edit
)