Representative money

Revision as of 23:23, 1 May 2025 by imported>Zero Contradictions (Changing short description from "Any type of money that has face value greater than its value as material substance" to "Money whose face value is greater than its physical value")
(diff) ← Previous revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)

Template:Short description

File:Goldcertificate front.jpg
U.S. $50 gold certificate

Representative money or receipt money is any medium of exchange, physical or digital, that represents something of value, but has little or no value of its own (intrinsic value). Unlike some forms of fiat money (which may have no commodity backing), genuine representative money must have something of intrinsic value supporting the face value.<ref name=mundell/>

More specifically, the term representative money has been used variously to mean:

There is no concrete evidence that the clay tokens used as an accounting tool to keep track of warehouse stores in ancient Mesopotamia were also used as representative money. <ref name="Schmandt-Besserat">Denise Schmandt-Besserat, Tokens: their Significance for the Origin of Counting and Writing</ref><ref>Keynes, J.M. (1930). A Treatise on Money. Volume I, p. 13</ref> However, the idea has been suggested.<ref name=mundell/>

In 1895 economist Joseph Shield Nicholson wrote that credit expansion and contraction was in fact the expansion and contraction of representative money.<ref>Joseph Shield Nicholson, A treatise on money and essays on monetary problems], Chapter VI, Effects of Credit or "Representative Money" on prices, pp. 72–74, A. and C. Black, 1895.</ref>

In 1934 economist William Howard Steiner wrote that the term was used "at one time to signify that a certain amount of bullion was stored in the Treasury while the equivalent paper in circulation" represented the bullion.<ref name="p.30"/>

See alsoEdit

ReferencesEdit

Template:Reflist

Template:Means of Exchange