Thomas Schelling

Revision as of 20:01, 24 May 2025 by imported>OAbot (Open access bot: url-access updated in citation with #oabot.)
(diff) ← Previous revision | Latest revision (diff) | Newer revision → (diff)

Template:Short description Template:Use mdy dates Template:Infobox economist

Thomas Crombie Schelling (April 14, 1921 – December 13, 2016) was an American economist and professor of foreign policy, national security, nuclear strategy, and arms control at the School of Public Policy at the University of Maryland, College Park. He was also co-faculty at the New England Complex Systems Institute.

Schelling was awarded the 2005 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences (shared with Robert Aumann) for "having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game theory analysis."<ref name=":0" />

BiographyEdit

Early yearsEdit

Schelling was born on April 14, 1921, in Oakland, California.<ref name=":0">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> He graduated from San Diego High School. He received his bachelor's degree in economics from the University of California, Berkeley, in 1944 and received his PhD in economics from Harvard University in 1951.

CareerEdit

Schelling served with the Marshall Plan in Europe, the White House, and the Executive Office of the President from 1948 to 1953.<ref name=cv>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> He wrote most of his dissertation on national income behavior working at night while in Europe. He left government to join the economics faculty at Yale University.

In 1956, "he joined the RAND Corporation as an adjunct fellow, becoming a full-time researcher for a year after leaving Yale, and returning to adjunct status through 2002."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In 1958 Schelling was appointed professor of economics at Harvard. That same year, he "co-founded the Center for International Affairs, which was [later] renamed the Weatherhead Center for International Affairs."<ref name=":2">Template:Cite news</ref>

In 1969, Schelling joined Harvard's John F. Kennedy School of Government, where he was the Lucius N. Littauer Professor of Political Economy.<ref name="cv" /> He was among the "founding fathers" of the "modern" Kennedy School, as he helped to shift the curriculum's emphasis away from administration and more toward leadership.<ref name=":2" />

Between 1994 and 1999, he conducted research at the International Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA), in Laxenburg, Austria.

In 1990, he left Harvard and joined the University of Maryland School of Public Policy and the University of Maryland Department of Economics.<ref name=":1">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In 1991, he accepted the presidency of the American Economic Association, an organization of which he was also a Distinguished Fellow.<ref name=":3">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

In 1995, he accepted the presidency of the Eastern Economic Association.<ref name=":4">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

Schelling was a contributing participant of the Copenhagen Consensus.<ref name=cv /><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

Honors and awardsEdit

In 1977, Schelling received The Frank E. Seidman Distinguished Award in Political Economy.

In 1993, he was awarded the Award for Behavior Research Relevant to the Prevention of Nuclear War from the National Academy of Sciences.<ref name="NASNuclear">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

He received honorary doctorates from Erasmus University Rotterdam in 2003, Yale University in 2009, and RAND Graduate School of Public Analysis, as well as an honorary degree from the University of Manchester in 2010.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name=":4" /><ref name=":3" />

He was awarded the 2005 Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences, along with Robert Aumann, for "having enhanced our understanding of conflict and cooperation through game-theory analysis."<ref name=":0" />

In 2008 he was the Witten Lecturer at the Witten/Herdecke University as the awardee of the Witten Lectures in Economics and Philosophy.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

Personal life and deathEdit

Schelling was married to Corinne Tigay Saposs from 1947 to 1991, with whom he had four sons. Later in 1991 he married Alice M. Coleman, who brought two sons to the marriage; they became his stepsons.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>Template:Cite news</ref>

Schelling died on December 13, 2016, in Bethesda, Maryland, from complications following a hip fracture at the age of 95.<ref name=":1" />

Schelling's family auctioned his Nobel award medal, fetching $187,000. They donated this money to the Southern Poverty Law Center, an American 501 nonprofit legal advocacy organization specializing in civil rights and public interest litigation. Alice Schelling said her late husband had credited Smoky the Cowhorse by Will James, the winner of the Newbery Medal in 1927, as the most influential book he had read.<ref>Levin, Sala (June 8, 2018). Family of Late UMD Professor Auctions Nobel Medal to Fight Hate. http://terp.umd.edu/</ref>

Notable worksEdit

Template:Anchor

The Strategy of Conflict (1960)Edit

The Strategy of Conflict, which Schelling published in 1960,<ref name=":5">Template:Cite book</ref> pioneered the study of bargaining and strategic behavior in what he refers to as "conflict behavior."<ref name=":12">Template:Cite journal</ref> The Times Literary Supplement in 1995 ranked it as one of the 100 most influential books in the 50 years since 1945.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In this book Schelling introduced concepts such as the "focal point" and "credible commitment." In a 1961 review, International Relations scholar Morton Kaplan described the book as a "strikingly original contribution" and a "landmark in the literature."<ref name="Kaplan 1961 642–652">Template:Cite journal</ref>

Schelling's book comprised a series of scholarly journal articles that he had published over the period 1957–1960.<ref name="Kaplan 1961 642–652"/>

Schelling encourages in his work a strategic view toward conflict that is equally "rational" and "successful."<ref name=":5" /> He believes that conflict cannot be based merely on one's intelligence but must also address the "advantages" associated with a course of action. He considers that the advantages that are gleaned should be firmly fixed in a value system that is both "explicit" and "consistent."<ref name=":5" />

Also, conflict has a distinct meaning. In Schelling's approach, it is not enough to defeat an opponent, but one must also seize opportunities to co-operate of which there are usually many. He points out that it is only on the rarest of occasions, in what is known as "pure conflict," that the participants' interests are implacably opposed.<ref name=":5" /> He uses the example of "a war of complete extermination" to illustrate this phenomenon.<ref name=":5" />

Co-operation, if available, may take many forms and thus potentially involve everything from "deterrence, limited war, and disarmament" to "negotiation."<ref name=":5" /> Indeed, it is through such actions that participants are left with less of a conflict and more of a "bargaining situation."<ref name=":5" /> The bargaining itself is best thought of in terms of the other participant's actions, as any gains one might realize are highly dependent upon the "choices or decisions" of their opponent.<ref name=":5" />

Communication between parties, though, is another matter entirely. Verbal or written communication is known as "explicit," and involves such activities as "offering concessions."<ref name=":5" /> What happens, though, when this type of communication becomes impossible or improbable? This is when something called "tacit maneuvers" become important.<ref name=":5" /> Think of this as action-based communication. Schelling uses the example of one's occupation or evacuation of strategic territory to illustrate this latter communication method.

In an article celebrating Schelling's Nobel Memorial Prize for Economics,<ref>"A Nobel Laureate Who's Got Game", The Washington Post, October 12, 2005.</ref> Michael Kinsley, Washington Post op‑ed columnist and one of Schelling's former students, anecdotally summarizes Schelling's reorientation of game theory thus: "[Y]ou're standing at the edge of a cliff, chained by the ankle to someone else. You'll be released, and one of you will get a large prize, as soon as the other gives in. How do you persuade the other guy to give in, when the only method at your disposal—threatening to push him off the cliff—would doom you both? Answer: You start dancing, closer and closer to the edge. That way, you don't have to convince him that you would do something totally irrational: plunge him and yourself off the cliff. You just have to convince him that you are prepared to take a higher risk than he is of accidentally falling off the cliff. If you can do that, you win."

Arms and Influence (1966)Edit

Schelling's theories about war were extended in Arms and Influence, published in 1966.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> According to the publisher, the book "carries forward the analysis so brilliantly begun in his earlier The Strategy of Conflict (1960) and Strategy and Arms Control (with Morton Halperin, 1961), and makes a significant contribution to the growing literature on modern war and diplomacy." Chapter headings include The Diplomacy of Violence, The Diplomacy of Ultimate Survival and The Dynamics of Mutual Alarm.

Within the work, Schelling discusses military capabilities and how they can be used as bargaining power. Instead of considering only the choices that are available on a surface level, one can think ahead to try to influence the other party to come to the desired conclusion. Specifically, Schelling mentions the actions taken by the U.S. during the Cuban and Berlin crises and how they functioned as not only preparation for war but also signals. For example, Schelling points out that the bombing of North Vietnam "is as much coercive as tactical."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Not only was the bombing to cripple their enemies armies, but it also served to bring Vietnam to the table for negotiations. Much of this writing was influenced largely due to Schelling's personal interest in Game Theory and its application to nuclear armaments.

Schelling's work influenced Robert Jervis.<ref name=":02">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

Micromotives and Macrobehavior (1978)Edit

In 1969 and 1971, Schelling published widely cited articles dealing with racial dynamics and what he termed "a general theory of tipping."<ref>Thomas C. Schelling (1969) "Models of segregation," American Economic Review, 1969, 59(2), 488–493.
   _____ (1971). "Dynamic Models of Segregation," Journal of Mathematical Sociology, 1(2), pp. 143–186.</ref> In those papers, he showed that a preference that one's neighbors be of the same color, or even a preference for a mixture "up to some limit," can lead to total segregation. He thus argued that motives, malicious or not, were indistinguishable as to explaining the phenomenon of complete local separation of distinct groups. He used coins on graph paper to demonstrate his theory by placing pennies and dimes in different patterns on the "board" and then moving them one by one if they were in an "unhappy" situation.Template:Citation needed

Schelling's dynamics has been cited as a way of explaining variations that are found in what are regarded as meaningful differencesTemplate:Spaced ndashgender, age, race, ethnicity, language, sexual preference, and religion. A cycle of such change, once it has begun, may have a self-sustaining momentum. Schelling's 1978 book Micromotives and Macrobehavior expanded on and generalized those themes<ref>Thomas C. Schelling (1978) Micromotives and Macrobehavior, Norton. Description, preview.</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> and is often cited in the literature of agent-based computational economics.

Global warmingEdit

Schelling was involved in the global warming debate since chairing a commission for President Jimmy Carter in 1980. He believed climate change poses a serious threat to developing nations, but that the threat to the United States was exaggerated. He wrote that,

Today, little of our gross domestic product is produced outdoors, and therefore, little is susceptible to climate. Agriculture and forestry are less than 3 percent of total output, and little else is much affected. Even if agricultural productivity declined by a third over the next half-century, the per capita GNP we might have achieved by 2050 we would still achieve in 2051. Considering that agricultural productivity in most parts of the world continues to improve (and that many crops may benefit directly from enhanced photosynthesis due to increased carbon dioxide), it is not at all certain that the net impact on agriculture will be negative or much noticed in the developed world.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>

Template:Further

Drawing on his experience with the Marshall Plan after World War II, he argued that addressing global warming is a bargaining problem: if the world were able to reduce emissions, poor countries would receive most of the benefits, but rich countries would bear most of the costs.

Contributions to popular cultureEdit

Stanley Kubrick read an article Schelling wrote that included a description of the Peter George novel Red Alert, and conversations between Kubrick, Schelling, and George eventually led to the 1964 movie Dr. Strangelove or: How I Learned to Stop Worrying and Love the Bomb.<ref>Thomas C. Schelling, 2006 prologue to 'Meteors, Mischief, and War', in Strategies of commitment and other essays, Harvard University Press, 2006.</ref>

Schelling is also cited for the first known use of the phrase collateral damage in his May 1961 article Dispersal, Deterrence, and Damage.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>

In his book Choice and Consequence,<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> he explored various topics such as nuclear terrorism, blackmail, daydreaming, and euthanasia, from a behavioral economics point of view.

See alsoEdit

ReferencesEdit

Template:Reflist

External linksEdit

Template:Sister project Template:Sister project

|CitationClass=web }} Template:S-start Template:S-ach Template:S-bef Template:S-ttl Template:S-aft Template:S-end Template:Nobel laureates in economics 2001–2025 Template:2005 Nobel Prize winners Template:Presidents of the American Economic Association Template:Authority control