Template:Short description Template:Distinguish Template:Infobox economist

John Rogers Commons (October 13, 1862 – May 11, 1945) was an American institutional economist, Georgist, progressive and labor historian at the University of Wisconsin–Madison.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>

Early yearsEdit

John R. Commons was born in Hollansburg, Ohio on October 13, 1862. Commons had a religious upbringing which led him to be an advocate for social justice early in life. Commons was considered a poor student and suffered from a mental illness while studying. He was allowed to graduate without finishing because of the potential seen in his intense determination and curiosity. At this time, Commons became a follower of Henry George's 'single tax' economics.<ref>Brue S. and Grant R. (2012). The Evolution of Economic Thought (PDF) (Supplemental Biography of John Rogers Commons for chapter 19 of the online edition of The Evolution of Economic Thought ed.). Cengage Learning. Retrieved 1 September 2014.</ref> He carried this 'Georgist' or 'Ricardian' approach to economics, with a focus on land and monopoly rents, throughout the rest of his life, including a proposal for income taxes with higher rates on land rents.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Henry George's Resurrection of the Science of Political Economy (Part Three) Edward J. Dodson http://cooperative-individualism.org/dodson-edward_henry-george-resurrection-of-political-economy-1996-03.htm Template:Webarchive</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>"Two Centuries of Economic Thought on Taxation of Land Rents." In Richard Lindholm and Arthur Lynn, Jr., (eds.), Land Value Taxation in Thought and Practice. Madison: Univ. of Wisconsin Press, 1982, pp. 151-96. http://www.masongaffney.org/publications/K142_Centuries_Thought_Land_Taxation.CV.pdf</ref>

After graduating from Oberlin College, Commons did two years of graduate studies at Johns Hopkins University, where he studied under Richard T. Ely,<ref name=HDPE>J. David Hoeveler, Jr., "John R. Commons," Historical Dictionary of the Progressive Era, 1890–1920. Revised Edition. Westport, CT: Greenwood Press, 1988; pp. 85–86.</ref> but left without a degree.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref> After appointments at Oberlin and Indiana University, Commons began teaching at Syracuse University in 1895.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

In spring 1899, Syracuse dismissed him as a radical.<ref>Richard A. Gonce (2002), "John R. Commons's "Five Big Years": 1899–1904", The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, Vol. 61, No. 4 (Oct., 2002), pp. i+755–777, p. 756</ref> Eventually Commons re-entered academia at the University of Wisconsin in 1904.<ref name=HDPE />

Commons' early work exemplified his desire to unite Christian ideals with the emerging social sciences of sociology and economics. He was a frequent contributor to Kingdom magazine, was a founder of the American Institute for Christian Sociology, and authored a book in 1894 called Social Reform and the Church.<ref name="Hoeveler pg. 85">Hoeveler, "John R. Commons," pg. 85.</ref> He was an advocate of temperance legislation and was active in the national Prohibition Party.<ref name="Hoeveler pg. 85"/> By his Wisconsin years, Commons' scholarship had become less moralistic and more empirical, and he moved away from a religious viewpoint in his ethics and sociology.<ref>Gonce, Richard A. “John R. Commons's 'Five Big Years': 1899-1904.” The American Journal of Economics and Sociology, vol. 61, no. 4, 2002, pp. 760-i. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/3487977.</ref>

CareerEdit

File:JohnCommons.jpg
John R. Commons at his desk at the University of Wisconsin in the 1920s.

Commons is best known for developing an analysis of collective action by the state and other institutions, which he saw as essential to understanding economics. Commons believed that carefully crafted legislation could create social change; that view led him to be known as a socialist radical and incrementalist. Contrary to some published accounts, Commons did consider African Americans capable of voting. When he advocated proportional representation, he suggested a "negro party".<ref>Commons, John, R. 1900. Representative Democracy. New York: American Bureau of Economic Research, 1900, 20.</ref> He even suggested applying the Thirteenth amendment to the Constitution to force Southern States to allow African Americans to vote.<ref>Chasse, John Dennis. A Workers' Economist: John R. Commons and His Legacy from Progressivism to the War on Poverty. New York: Transactions Press, pp.120-122.</ref> He continued the strong American tradition in institutional economics by such figures as the economist and social theorist Thorstein Veblen. His notion of transaction is one of the most important contributions to Institutional Economics.<ref>Nicita A. and M. Vatiero (2007), "The Contract and the Market: Towards a Broader Notion of Transaction?". Studi e Note di Economia, 1:7–22. Link Template:Webarchive</ref> The institutional theory was closely related to his remarkable successes in fact-finding and drafting legislation on a wide range of social issues for the state of Wisconsin. He drafted legislation establishing Wisconsin's worker's compensation program, the first of its kind in the United States.

In 1906, Commons co-founded the American Association for Labor Legislation (AALL) with other economists.<ref name=DAMoss> Template:Cite journal</ref>

Commons was a contributor to The Pittsburgh Survey, a 1907 sociological investigation of a single American city. His graduate student, John A. Fitch, wrote The Steel Workers, a classic depiction of a key industry in early 20th-century America. It was one of six key texts to come out of the survey. Edwin E. Witte, later known as the "father of social security" also did his PhD at the University of Wisconsin–Madison under Commons.

He was a leading advocate of proportional representation in the United States, writing a book on the subject in 1907 and serving as vice-president of the Proportional Representation League.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

Commons undertook two major studies of the history of labor unions in the United States. Beginning in 1910, he edited A Documentary History of American Industrial Society, a large work that preserved many original-source documents of the American labor movement. Almost as soon as that work was complete, Commons began editing History of Labor in the United States, a narrative work which built on the previous 10-volume documentary history.

The first national honor society in economics, Omicron Delta Gamma (ODG), was formed on May 7, 1915, by the merger of Harvard University's Undergraduate Society of Economics with the University of Wisconsin's Order of Artus, an economics student society modeled on King Arthur's Knights of the Roundtable; Wisconsin's group was advised by Commons.

In 1934, Commons published Institutional Economics, which laid out his view that institutions were made up of collective actions that, along with conflict of interests, defined the economy. He believed that institutional economics added collective control of individual transactions to existing economic theory.<ref>Vatiero, Massimiliano. "From W. N. Hohfeld to J. R. Commons, and Beyond? A "Law and Economics" Enquiry on Jural Relations", American Journal of Economics and Sociology, 69(2): 840–866, 2010.</ref> Commons considered the Scottish economist Henry Dunning Macleod to be the "originator" of Institutional economics.<ref name="isbn0-88738-797-7">Template:Cite book</ref>

Commons was elected to the American Philosophical Society in 1936.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

Death and legacyEdit

File:Hocheera.jpg
The John R. and Nell Commons House Landmark Designation Sign

He died on May 11, 1945.

Today, Commons's contribution to labor history is considered equal to his contributions to the theory of institutional economics. He also made valuable contributions to the history of economic thought, especially with regard to collective action. He is honored at the University of Wisconsin in Madison with rooms and clubs named for him.<ref>The John R. Commons Room on the 8th floor of the Sociology building, and the John R. Commons Club in the Economics department</ref>

Commons was the mentor of many outstanding economists and has been credited with originating the "Wisconsin Idea," in which university faculty serve as advisors to state government.<ref>

File:Hocheera.jpg
The John R. and Nell Commons House Landmark Designation Sign

</ref>

His former home, The John R. and Nell Commons House, is listed on the National Register of Historic Places.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>

The John R. Commons Award is awarded biennially to an outstanding economist in recognition of academic achievements and for service both to the economics profession and to Omicron Delta Epsilon.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> The award is given at American Economic Association conference where the honoree presents a "Commons Lecture" which is later published in The American Economist. Over the years, the Commons Award has served as an indicator of recipients of the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences. Nine Commons Award winners have won the Nobel Prize; most recently, Claudia Goldin (2009) won the Nobel in 2023.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>

QuotesEdit

  • "An institution is defined as collective action in control, liberation and expansion of individual action." —"Institutional Economics" American Economic Review, vol. 21 (December 1931), pp. 648–657.
  • "...But the smallest unit of the institutional economists is a unit of activity — a transaction, with its participants. Transactions intervene between the labor of the classic economists and the pleasures of the hedonic economists, simply because it is society that controls access to the forces of nature, and transactions are, not the "exchange of commodities," but the alienation and acquisition, between individuals, of the rights of property and liberty created by society, which must therefore be negotiated between the parties concerned before labor can produce, or consumers can consume, or commodities be physically exchanged..." —"Institutional Economics" American Economic Review, vol. 21 (December 1931), pp. 648–657.

PublicationsEdit

Solely authored works

Co-authored works

Edited works

  • Commons, John R. (Ed.). Trade Unionism and Labor Problems. Boston: Ginn and Co., 1905.
  • Commons, John R. (Ed.). A Documentary History of American Industrial Society. In 10 Volumes. Cleveland, Ohio: Arthur H. Clark Co., 1910.

See alsoEdit

NotesEdit

Template:Reflist

ReferencesEdit

  • Barbash, Jack. "John R. Commons: Pioneer of Labor Economics," Monthly Labor Review 112:5 (May 1989) [1]
  • Chasse, John, Dennis."A Worker's Economist: John R. Commons and His Legacy from Progressivism to the War on Poverty.New York: Transactions Press,2017
  • Coats, A.W. "John R. Commons as a Historian of Economics: The Quest for the Antecedents of Collective Action" in Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Vol.1, 1983.

Commons, John, R. 1900. Representative Democracy. New York: American Bureau of Economic Research, 1900. Available at https://babel.hathitrust.org/cgi/pt?id=coo.31924032462842&view=1up&seq=18

  • Commons, John R. Myself. Reprint ed. University of Wisconsin Press, 1964.
  • Cranfill, Samuel Elliott (1940). "Recent Contributions of John R. Commons to Economic Thought". Southern Economic Journal. 7 (1): 63–79.
  • Dorfman, Joseph. The Economic Mind in American Civilization: 1918–1933. Vols. 4 and 5. Reissue ed. New York: Augustus M. Kelley Publications, 1969. Template:ISBN
  • Fitch, John A. The Steel Workers. Reprint ed. University of Pittsburgh Press, 1910 (1989). Template:ISBN.
  • Parson, Kenneth. "John R. Commons Point of View," Journal of Land and Public Utility Economics (Land Economics) 18(3):245–60 (1942).
  • Samuels, Warren. "Reader's Guide to John R. Commons Legal Foundations of Capitalism," in Warren Samuels, ed. Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology, Archival Supplement 5, Amsterdam: Elsevier 1996.
  • Tichi, Cecelia. "John R. Commons: The Pittsburgh Survey," in "Civic Passions: Seven Who Launched Progressive America (And What They Teach Us)." University of North Carolina Press, 2009.
  • Kemp, Thomas. Progress and Reform, VDM Verlag, 2009.
  • Fiorito Luca, and Massimiliano Vatiero (2011), "Beyond Legal Relations: Wesley Newcomb Hohfeld's Influence on American Institutionalism". Journal of Economics Issues, 45 (1): 199–222.

External linksEdit

Template:Sister project

Template:Instecon Template:Presidents of the American Economic Association Template:Authority control