Open main menu
Home
Random
Recent changes
Special pages
Community portal
Preferences
About Wikipedia
Disclaimers
Incubator escapee wiki
Search
User menu
Talk
Dark mode
Contributions
Create account
Log in
Editing
Negative responsiveness
(section)
Warning:
You are not logged in. Your IP address will be publicly visible if you make any edits. If you
log in
or
create an account
, your edits will be attributed to your username, along with other benefits.
Anti-spam check. Do
not
fill this in!
== Frequency of violations == The frequency of negative response will depend on the electoral method, the candidates, and the distribution of outcomes. ===Empirical analysis=== In the US, a 2021 analysis of [[Instant-runoff voting|instant-runoff]] elections in California between 2008 and 2016, as well as the [[2009 Burlington, Vermont mayoral election]], found an upward monotonicity anomaly rate of 0.74% (1/135) in all elections, 2.71% (1/37) when limited to elections going to a second round of counting and 7.7% (1/13) of elections with three competitive candidates.<ref>{{cite journal |last1=Graham-Squire |first1=Adam |last2=Zayatz |first2=N. |title=Lack of Monotonicity Anomalies in Empirical Data of Instant-runoff Elections |journal=Representation |date=2 October 2021 |volume=57 |issue=4 |pages=565β573 |doi=10.1080/00344893.2020.1785536}}</ref><ref name="McCune"/> A more comprehensive 2023 survey of 182 American IRV elections where no candidate was ranked first by a majority of voters found seven total examples of non-monotonicity (3.8%), broken down into 2.2% (4/182) examples of upward monotonicity, 1.6% (3/182) of downward montonicity and 0.5% (1/182) of no-show or truncation (one example was both an upward and downward monotonicity failure).<ref name=":522" /><ref name="McCune">{{cite journal |last1=McCune |first1=David |last2=Graham-Squire |first2=Adam |title=Monotonicity anomalies in Scottish local government elections |journal=Social Choice and Welfare |date=August 2024 |volume=63 |issue=1 |pages=69β101 |doi=10.1007/s00355-024-01522-5 |doi-access=free|arxiv=2305.17741 }}</ref> Two of those elections are also noted as specific examples below. ====Semi-empirical==== Some empirical research do not have access to full ballot preference data, and thus make probabilistic estimates of transfer patterns. A 2013 survey of Irish elections using IRV and [[PR-STV]] found plausible non-monotonicity in 20 out of 1326 elections between 1922 and 2011.<ref name="Gallagher">{{Cite conference |last=Gallagher |first=Michael |date=September 2013 |title=Monotonicity and non-monotonicity at PR-STV elections |url=https://www.lancaster.ac.uk/fass/events/epop2013/docs/MGallagherMonotonicityEPOP13.pdf |conference=Annual conference of the elections, public opinion and parties (EPOP) specialist group, University of Lancaster |volume=13}}</ref> Data from the five UK general elections between 1992 and 2010 showed 2642 three candidate elections in English constituencies. With second preferences imputed from survey data, 1.7% of all elections appeared vulnerable to monotonicity anomalies (1.4% upward, 0.3% downward), significantly lower than simulated datasets from the same paper. However, when limited to the 4.2% of elections considered three-way competitive<!--This should be the 111 elections where PL support >25% but might need to check that, also probably get consensus that it's correct per CALC-->, 40.2% appeared vulnerable (33% upward, 7.1% downward), and further increasing with closer competition, a result closer to the simulations.<ref name=":3">{{Cite journal |last=Miller |first=Nicholas R. |date=October 2017 |title=Closeness matters: monotonicity failure in IRV elections with three candidates |url=https://userpages.umbc.edu/~nmiller/MONFAILURE.R2.NRM.pdf |journal=Public Choice |volume=173 |issue=1β2 |pages=91β108 |doi=10.1007/s11127-017-0465-5 |quote=Impartial Culture Profiles: All, TMF: 15.1% |hdl-access=free |hdl=11603/20938}}</ref> A 2022 analysis out of the 10 French presidential elections (conducted under the [[two-round system]]) 2 had results where monotonicity violations were not mathematically possible, another 6 where violations were unlikely given the evidence, leaving 2 elections ([[2002 French presidential election|2002]] and [[2007 French presidential election|2007]]) where an upward monotonicity violation was probable and likely respectively.<ref name=":4">{{cite journal |last1=Keskin |first1=Umut |last2=Sanver |first2=M. Remzi |last3=Tosunlu |first3=H. Berkay |url=https://hal.science/hal-03413280/document |title=Monotonicity violations under plurality with a runoff: the case of French presidential elections |journal=Social Choice and Welfare |date=August 2022 |volume=59 |issue=2 |pages=305β333 |doi=10.1007/s00355-022-01397-4}}</ref> === Theoretical models=== Results using the [[impartial culture]] model estimate about 15% of elections with 3 candidates;<ref>{{Cite web |last=Miller |first=Nicholas R. |date=2016 |title=Monotonicity Failure in IRV Elections with Three Candidates: Closeness Matters |url=https://userpages.umbc.edu/~nmiller/MONFAILURE.R2.NRM.pdf |access-date=2020-07-26 |website=University of Maryland Baltimore County |at=Table 2 |language=en |quote=Impartial Culture Profiles: All, TMF: 15.1% |edition=2nd}}</ref><ref name="Miller2012"/> however, the true probability may be much higher, especially when restricting observation to close elections.<ref name=":2">{{Cite journal |last=Quas |first=Anthony |date=2004-03-01 |title=Anomalous Outcomes in Preferential Voting |url=https://www.worldscientific.com/doi/abs/10.1142/S0219493704000912 |journal=Stochastics and Dynamics |language=en |volume=04 |issue=1 |pages=95β105 |doi=10.1142/S0219493704000912 |issn=0219-4937|url-access=subscription }}</ref> A 2013 study using a two-dimensional [[spatial model of voting]] estimated at least 15% of IRV elections would be nonmonotonic in the best-case scenario (with only three equally-competitive candidates). The researchers concluded that "three-way competitive races will exhibit unacceptably frequent monotonicity failures" and "In light of these results, those seeking to implement a fairer multi-candidate election system should be wary of adopting IRV."<ref name="Ornstein" /> === Specific examples === ==== 2022 in Alaska ==== [[2022 Alaska's at-large congressional district special election|Alaska's first-ever instant-runoff election]] resulted in a victory for [[Democratic Party (United States)|Democrat]] [[Mary Peltola]], but had many voters for [[Republican Party (United States)|Republican]] [[Sarah Palin]] instead ranked Peltola first, Peltola would have lost.<ref>{{Cite journal |last1=Graham-Squire |first1=Adam |last2=McCune |first2=David |date=2024-01-02 |title=Ranked Choice Wackiness in Alaska |url=https://www.tandfonline.com/doi/full/10.1080/10724117.2023.2224675 |journal=Math Horizons |language=en |volume=31 |issue=1 |pages=24β27 |doi=10.1080/10724117.2023.2224675 |issn=1072-4117|url-access=subscription }}</ref> ==== Burlington, Vermont ==== In [[2009 Burlington, Vermont mayoral election|Burlington's second IRV election]], incumbent [[Bob Kiss]] was re-elected, despite losing in a head-to-head matchup with Democrat Andy Montroll (the [[Condorcet winner]]). However, if Kiss had gained more support from Wright voters, Kiss would have lost.<ref name=":522" /> ==== 2005 German election in Dresden ==== In the [[2005 German federal election]], [[Christian Democratic Union of Germany|CDU]] supporters in [[Dresden]] were instructed to vote for the [[Free Democratic Party (Germany)|FDP]], a strategy that allowed the CDU to win an additional seat.<ref name=":4222" /> This led the [[Federal Constitutional Court]] to rule that negative responsiveness violates the [[Basic Law for the Federal Republic of Germany|German constitution]]'s guarantee of [[One man, one vote|equal and direct suffrage]].<ref name=":0322"/>
Edit summary
(Briefly describe your changes)
By publishing changes, you agree to the
Terms of Use
, and you irrevocably agree to release your contribution under the
CC BY-SA 4.0 License
and the
GFDL
. You agree that a hyperlink or URL is sufficient attribution under the Creative Commons license.
Cancel
Editing help
(opens in new window)