Carbon tax
Template:Short description Template:Use dmy dates
A carbon tax is a tax levied on the carbon emissions from producing goods and services. Carbon taxes are intended to make visible the hidden social costs of carbon emissions. They are designed to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by essentially increasing the price of fossil fuels. This both decreases demand for goods and services that produce high emissions and incentivizes making them less carbon-intensive.<ref name=":0">Template:Cite journal</ref> When a fossil fuel such as coal, petroleum, or natural gas is burned, most or all of its carbon is converted to Template:CO2. Greenhouse gas emissions cause climate change. This negative externality can be reduced by taxing carbon content at any point in the product cycle.<ref name="CollectionPoint">Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite news</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref name="bashmakov">Template:Cite book</ref>
A carbon tax as well as carbon emission trading is used within the carbon price concept. Two common economic alternatives to carbon taxes are tradable permits with carbon credits and subsidies. In its simplest form, a carbon tax covers only Template:CO2 emissions. It could also cover other greenhouse gases, such as methane or nitrous oxide, by taxing such emissions based on their Template:CO2-equivalent global warming potential.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Research shows that carbon taxes do often reduce emissions.<ref name=":3">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Many economists argue that carbon taxes are the most efficient (lowest cost) way to tackle climate change.<ref name="gupta taxes and charges">Template:Cite book</ref><ref name=":5">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Template:As of, carbon taxes have either been implemented or are scheduled for implementation in 25 countries.<ref>Template:Cite report p. 24, Fig. 6</ref> 46 countries have put some form of price on carbon, either through carbon taxes or carbon emission trading schemes.<ref>Template:Cite report p. 21</ref>
Some experts observe that a carbon tax can negatively affect public welfare, tending to hit low- and middle-income households the hardest and making their necessities more expensive (for instance, the tax might drive up prices for, say, petrol and electricity<ref name=":11" />). Alternatively, the tax can be too conservative, making "comparatively small dents in overall emissions".<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> To make carbon taxes fairer, policymakers can try to redistribute the revenue generated from carbon taxes to low-income groups by various fiscal means.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref><ref name=":10">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Such a policy initiative becomes a carbon fee and dividend, rather than a plain tax.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>Template:Toclimit
PurposeEdit
Template:Further Template:Climate change mitigation
Carbon dioxide is one of several heat-trapping greenhouse gases (others include methane and water vapor) emitted as a result of human activities. The scientific consensus is that human-induced greenhouse gas emissions are the primary cause of climate change,<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> and that carbon dioxide is the most important of the anthropogenic greenhouse gases.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Worldwide, 27 billion tonnes of carbon dioxide are produced by human activity annually.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref> The physical effect of Template:CO2 in the atmosphere can be measured as a change in the Earth-atmosphere system's energy balanceTemplate:Sndthe radiative forcing of Template:CO2.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref>
Different greenhouse gases have different physical properties: the global warming potential is an internationally accepted scale of equivalence for other greenhouse gases in units of tonnes of carbon dioxide equivalent. Carbon taxes are designed to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by increasing prices of the fossil fuels that emit them when burned. This both decreases demand for goods and services that produce high emissions and incentivizes making them less carbon-intensive.<ref name=":0" />
Economic theoryEdit
History and RationaleEdit
A carbon tax is a form of pollution tax.<ref>Template:Cite encyclopedia</ref> David Gordon Wilson first proposed this type of tax in 1973.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Unlike classic command and control regulations, which explicitly limit or prohibit emissions by each individual polluter,<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> a carbon tax aims to allow market forces to determine the most efficient way to reduce pollution.<ref name="regulate pollution">Template:Cite news</ref> A carbon tax is an indirect tax—a tax on a transaction—as opposed to a direct tax, which taxes income. Carbon taxes are price instruments since they set a price rather than an emission limit.<ref name="Hepburn">Template:Cite journal</ref>
In addition to creating incentives for energy conservation, a carbon tax puts renewable energy such as wind, solar and geothermal on a more competitive footing. In economic theory, pollution is considered a negative externality, a negative effect on a third party not directly involved in a transaction, and is a type of market failure. To confront the issue, economist Arthur Pigou proposed taxing the goods (in this case hydrocarbon fuels), that were the source of the externality (Template:Chem) so as to accurately reflect the cost of the goods to society, thereby internalizing the production costs. A tax on a negative externality is called a Pigovian tax, which should equal the cost.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
Within Pigou's framework, the changes involved are marginal, and the size of the externality is assumed to be small enough not to distort the economy.<ref name="helmsocial">Template:Cite journal</ref> Climate change is claimed to result in catastrophe (non-marginal) changes.<ref name="helmsurvey">Template:Cite book</ref><ref>Template:Cite book</ref> "Non-marginal" means that the impact could significantly reduce the growth rate in income and welfare. The amount of resources that should be devoted to climate change mitigation is controversial.<ref name="helmsurvey" /> Policies designed to reduce carbon emissions could have a non-marginal impact, but are asserted to not be catastrophic.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
DesignEdit
The design of a carbon tax involves two primary factors: the level of the tax, and the use of the revenue.<ref name="auto1">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> The former is based on the social cost of carbon (SCC), which attempts to calculate the numeric cost of the externalities of carbon pollution. The precise number is the subject of debate in environmental and policy circles. A higher SCC corresponds with a higher evaluation of the costs of carbon pollution on society. Stanford University scientists have estimated the social cost of carbon to be upwards of $200 per ton.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> More conservative estimates pin the cost at around $50.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
The use of the revenue is another subject of debate in carbon tax proposals.<ref name="auto1" /> A government may use revenue to increase its discretionary spending, or address deficits. However, such proposals often run the risk of being regressive, and sparking backlash among the public due to an increased cost of energy associated with such taxes.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref> To avoid this and increase the popularity of a carbon tax, a government may make the carbon tax revenue-neutral.<ref name="auto">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> This can be done by reducing income tax proportionate to the level of the carbon tax, or by returning carbon tax revenues to citizens as a dividend.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Carbon leakageEdit
Carbon leakage happens when the regulation of emissions in one country/sector pushes those emissions to other places that with less regulation.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Leakage effects can be both negative (i.e., increasing the effectiveness of reducing overall emissions) and positive (reducing the effectiveness of reducing overall emissions).<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Negative leakages, which are desirable, can be referred to as "spill-over".<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
According to one study, short-term leakage effects need to be judged against long-term effects.<ref name=goldemberg>Template:Cite book</ref>Template:Rp A policy that, for example, establishes carbon taxes only in developed countries might leak emissions to developing countries. However, a desirable negative leakage could occur due to reduced demand for coal, oil, and gas in developed countries, lowering prices. This could allow developing countries to substitute oil or gas for coal, lowering emissions. In the long-run, however, if less polluting technologies are delayed, this substitution might have no long-term benefit. Carbon leakage is central to climate policy, given the 2030 Energy and Climate Framework and the review of the European Union's third carbon leakage list.<ref>Template:Cite report</ref>
Carbon tariffEdit
ImpactsEdit
Positive impactsEdit
Research shows that carbon taxes effectively reduce greenhouse gas emissions.<ref name=":3" /><ref name=":8">Template:Cite journal</ref><ref name=":9">Template:Cite journal</ref> Most economists assert that carbon taxes are the most efficient and effective way to curb climate change, with the least adverse economic effects.<ref name=":6">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name=":7">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name=":4">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name=":5" /><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> One study found that Sweden's carbon tax successfully reduced carbon dioxide emissions from transport by 11%.<ref name=":8" /> A 2015 British Columbia study found that the taxes reduced greenhouse gas emissions by 5–15% while having negligible overall economic effects.<ref name=":9" /> A 2017 British Columbia study found that industries on the whole benefited from the tax and "small but statistically significant 0.74 percent annual increases in employment" but that carbon-intensive and trade-sensitive industries were adversely affected.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> A 2020 study of carbon taxes in wealthy democracies showed that carbon taxes had not limited economic growth.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Carbon taxes also appear to not adversely affect employment or GDP growth in Europe.<ref name=":2">Template:Cite journal</ref> Their economic impact ranges from zero to modest positive.<ref name=":2" />
Negative impacts and trade-offsEdit
A number of studies have found that in the absence of an increase in social benefits and tax credits, a carbon tax would hit poor households harder than rich households.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref><ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Gilbert E. Metcalf disputed that carbon taxes would be regressive in the US.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Carbon taxes can increase electricity prices.<ref name=":11">Template:Cite news</ref> There is a debate about the relation between carbon pricing (like carbon emission trading and carbon tax) and climate justice. Carbon pricing can be adjusted to some principles of climate justice like polluters pay.<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> Many proponents of climate justice object to carbon pricing. To close the gap between the two concepts, carbon pricing could put a cap on emissions, remove pollution from underserved communities, and justly divide revenues.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
Support and oppositionEdit
Since carbon taxation was first proposed, numerous economists have described its strengths as a means of reducing CO2 pollution. This tax has been praised as "a far better way to control pollution than the present method of specific regulation."<ref>Template:Cite book</ref> It has also been lauded for its market based simplicity. This includes a description as "the most efficient way to guide the decisions of producers and consumers", since "carbon emissions have an 'unpriced' societal cost in terms of their deleterious effects on the earth's climate."<ref name="TysonNYT1">Template:Cite news</ref>
Carbon taxes have been opposed by a substantial proportion of the public. They have also been rejected in several elections, and in some cases reversed as opposition increased. One response has been to specifically allocate carbon tax revenues back to the public in order to garner support.<ref name="Mildenberger 141–147">Template:Cite journal</ref> Citizens' Climate Lobby is an international organization with over 500 chapters.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> It advocates for carbon tax legislation in the form of a progressive fee and dividend structure. NASA climatologist James E. Hansen has also spoken in favor of a revenue neutral carbon fee.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Since 2019 over 3,500 U.S. economists have signed The Economists' Statement on Carbon Dividends.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> This statement describes the benefits of a U.S. carbon tax along with suggestions for how it could be developed. One recommendation is to return revenues generated by a tax to the general public. The statement was originally signed by 45 Nobel Prize winning economists, former chairs of the Federal Reserve, former chairs of the CEA, and former secretaries of the Treasury Department.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref><ref>Template:Cite news</ref> It has been recognized as a historic example of consensus amongst economists.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Ben Ho, professor of economics at Vassar College, has argued that "while carbon taxes are part of the optimal portfolio of policies to fight climate change, they are not the most important part."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Public perceptionEdit
In some instances knowledge about how carbon tax revenues are used can affect public support. Dedicating revenues to climate projects and compensating low income housing have been found to be popular uses of revenue.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> However, providing information about specific revenue uses in countries that have implemented carbon taxes has been shown to have limited effectiveness in increasing public support.<ref name="Mildenberger 141–147" /> A 2021 poll conducted by GlobeScan on 31 countries and territories found that 62 percent on average are supportive of a carbon tax, while only 33 percent are opposed to a carbon tax. In 28 of the 31 countries and territories listed in the poll, a majority of their populations are supportive of a carbon tax.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
AlternativesEdit
Carbon emission tradingEdit
{{#invoke:Labelled list hatnote|labelledList|Main article|Main articles|Main page|Main pages}}
Carbon emission trading (also called cap and trade) is another approach. Emission levels are limited and emission permits traded among emitters. The permits can be issued via government auctions or by offered without charge based on existing emissions (grandfathering). Auctions raise revenues that can be used to reduce other taxes or to fund government programs.<ref name="smith">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Variations include setting price-floor and/or price-ceiling for permits.<ref name="Hepburn" /> A carbon tax can be combined with trading.<ref name="goldemberg" /> A cap with grandfathered permits can have an efficiency advantage since it applies to all industries. Cap and trade provides an equal incentive for all producers at the margin to reduce their emissions. This is an advantage over a tax that exempts or has reduced rates for certain sectors.<ref name="smith" />
Both carbon taxes and trading systems aim to reduce emissions by creating a price for emitting Template:CO2.<ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016">Jacobsen, Mark. "Environmental Economics Lecture 6–7." UCSD Econ 131. Econ 131 Lecture, 20 October 2016, San Diego, UCSD.</ref> In the absence of uncertainty both systems will result in the efficient market quantity and price of Template:CO2.<ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016" /><ref name="lse.ac.uk">"Which Is Better: Carbon Tax or Cap-and-Trade?" Grantham Research Institute on Climate Change and the Environment, London School of Economics, 21 March 2014, London School of Economics/GranthamInstitute/faqs/which-is-better-carbon-tax-or-cap-and-trade/.</ref> When the environmental damage and therefore the appropriate tax of each unit of Template:CO2 cannot be accurately calculated, a permit system may be more advantageous.<ref name="lse.ac.uk" /> In the case of uncertainty regarding the costs of Template:CO2 abatement for firms, a tax is preferable.<ref name="lse.ac.uk" /><ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016" /><ref name="c2es.org">"Cap and Trade vs. Taxes." Center for Climate and Energy Solutions, Center for Climate and Energy Solutions, 24 October 2017, www.c2es.org/document/cap-and-trade-vs-taxes/.</ref> Permit systems regulate total emissions. In practice the limit has often been set so high that permit prices are not significant.<ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016" /> In the first phase of the European Union Emissions Trading System,<ref>"EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS)." Icapcarbonaction.com, International Carbon Action Partnership, 10 October 2017, icapcarbonaction.com/en/?option=com_etsmap&task=export&format=pdf&layout=list&systems[]=43</ref><ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016" /><ref name="c2es.org" /> firms reduced their emissions to their allotted quantity without the purchase of any additional permits.<ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016" /> This drove permit prices to nearly zero two years later, crashing the system and requiring reforms that would eventually appear in EUETS Phase 3.<ref name="Jacobsen, Mark 2016" /><ref>"EU Emissions Trading System (EU ETS)." Icapcarbonaction.com, International Carbon Action Partnership, 10 October 2017, icapcarbonaction.com/en/?option=com_etsmap&task=export&format=pdf&layout=list&systems[]=43.</ref>
The distinction between carbon taxes and permit systems can get blurred when hybrid systems are allowed. A hybrid sets limits on price movements, potentially softening the cap. When the price gets too high, the issuing authority issues additional permits at that price. A price floor may be breached when emissions are so low that no one needs to buy a permit.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref> Economist Gilbert Metcalf has proposed such a system, the Emissions Assurance Mechanism,<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> and the idea, in principle, has been adopted by the Climate Leadership Council.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> James E. Hansen argued in 2009 that emissions trading would only make money for banks and hedge funds and allow business-as-usual for the chief carbon-emitting industries.<ref>James Hansen. Storms of My Grandchildren Bloomsbury, London 2009 Template:ISBN p. 241.</ref><ref name="Randerson">Template:Cite news</ref>
Carbon offsets and creditsEdit
Other types of taxesEdit
Two related taxes are emissions taxes and energy taxes. An emissions tax on greenhouse gas emissions requires individual emitters to pay a fee, charge, or tax for every tonne of greenhouse gas,<ref name="gupta taxes and charges" /> while an energy tax is applied to the fuels themselves. In terms of climate change mitigation, a carbon tax is not a perfect substitute for an emissions tax.<ref name=":1">Template:Cite book</ref> For example, a carbon tax encourages reduced fuel use, but it does not encourage emissions reduction such as carbon capture and storage. Energy taxes increase the price of energy regardless of emissions.<ref name=":1" />Template:Rp
An ad valorem energy tax is levied according to the energy content of a fuel or the value of an energy product, which may or may not be consistent with the emitted greenhouse gas amounts and their respective global warming potentials. Studies indicate that to reduce emissions by a certain amount, ad valorem energy taxes would be more costly than carbon taxes.<ref name="bashmakov" /> However, although greenhouse gas emissions are an externality, using energy services may result in other negative externalities, e.g., air pollution not covered by the carbon tax (such as ammonia or fine particles). A combined carbon-energy tax may therefore be better at reducing air pollution than a carbon tax alone.Template:Citation needed
Any of these taxes can be combined with a rebate, where the money collected by the tax is returned to qualifying parties, taxing heavy emitters and subsidizing those that emit less carbon. Because carbon taxes only target carbon dioxide, they do not target other greenhouse gasses, such as methane, which have a greater warming potential.<ref name=":10" />
Petroleum (gasoline, diesel, jet fuel) taxesEdit
Many countries tax fuel directly; for example, the UK imposes a hydrocarbon oil duty directly on vehicle hydrocarbon oils, including petrol and diesel fuel. While a direct tax sends a clear signal to the consumer, its efficiency at influencing consumers' fuel use has been challenged for reasons including:<ref name="oecditf08">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
- Possible delays of a decade or more as inefficient vehicles are replaced by newer models and the older models filter through the fleet.
- Political pressures that deter policymakers from increasing taxes.
- Limited relationship between consumer decisions on fuel economy and fuel prices. Other efforts, such as fuel efficiency standards, or changing income tax rules on taxable benefits, may be more effective.
- The historical use of fuel taxes as a source of general revenue, given fuel's low price elasticity, which allows higher rates without reducing fuel volumes. In these circumstances, the policy rational may be unclear.
Vehicle fuel taxes may reduce the "rebound effect" that occurs when vehicle efficiency improves. Consumers may make additional journeys or purchase heavier and more powerful vehicles, offsetting the efficiency gains.<ref name="oecditf07">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
Comparison of alternativesEdit
A 2018 survey of leading economists found that 58% of the surveyed economists agreed with the assertion, "Carbon taxes are a better way to implement climate policy than cap-and-trade," 31% stated that they had no opinion or that it was uncertain, but none of the respondents disagreed.<ref name=":4" />
In a review study in 1996 the authors concluded that the choice between an international quota (cap) system, or an international carbon tax, remained ambiguous.<ref name=":1" />Template:Rp Another study in 2012 compared a carbon tax, emissions trading, and command-and-control regulation at the industry level, concluding that market-based mechanisms would perform better than emission standards in achieving emission targets without affecting industrial production.<ref>Template:Cite journal</ref>
ImplementationEdit
Both energy and carbon taxes have been implemented in response to commitments under the United Nations Framework Convention on Climate Change.<ref name="bashmakov" /> In most cases the tax is implemented in combination with exemptions. Indirect carbon prices, such as fuel taxes, are much more common than carbon taxes. In 2021, OECD reported that 67 of the 71 countries it assessed had some form of fuel tax. Only 39 had carbon taxes or ETSs. However, the use of carbon taxes is growing more quickly. In addition, several countries plan to further strengthen existing carbon taxes in the coming years, including Singapore, Canada and South Africa.<ref name="worldbank">Template:Cite book</ref>
Current carbon price policies, including carbon taxes, are still considered insufficient to create the kinds of changes in emissions that would be consistent with Paris Agreement goals. The International Monetary Fund, OECD, and others have stated that current fossil fuel prices generally fail to reflect environmental impacts.<ref name="worldbank" />
EuropeEdit
Template:Update Template:Further In Europe, many countries have imposed energy taxes or energy taxes based partly on carbon content.<ref name="bashmakov" /> These include Denmark, Finland, Germany, Ireland, Italy, the Netherlands, Norway, Slovenia, Sweden, Switzerland, and the UK. None of these countries have been able to introduce a uniform carbon tax for fuels in all sectors.<ref>Template:Cite journal See. Burgers, Irene J., and Stefan E. Weishaar. Designing Carbon taxes is not an easy task: legal perspectives. No. 559. WIFO Working Papers, 2018.</ref> Denmark is the first country to include livestock emissions in their carbon tax system.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
During the 1990s, a carbon/energy tax was proposed at the EU level but failed due to industrial lobbying.<ref name="pearce">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In 2010, the European Commission considered implementing a pan-European minimum tax on pollution permits purchased under the European Union Greenhouse Gas Emissions Trading Scheme (EU ETS) in which the proposed new tax would be calculated in terms of carbon content.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref> The suggested rate of €4 to €30 per tonne of Template:CO2.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
AmericasEdit
Costa RicaEdit
In 1997, Costa Rica imposed a 3.5 percent carbon tax on hydrocarbon fuels.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> A portion of the proceeds go to the "Payment for Environmental Services" (PSA) program which gives incentives to property owners to practice sustainable development and forest conservation.<ref>Template:Citation</ref> Approximately 11% of Costa Rica's national territory is protected by the plan.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> The program now pays out roughly $15 million a year to around 8,000 property owners.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
CanadaEdit
{{#invoke:Labelled list hatnote|labelledList|Main article|Main articles|Main page|Main pages}}
In the 2008 Canadian federal election, a carbon tax proposed by Liberal Party leader Stéphane Dion, known as the Green Shift, became a central issue. It would have been revenue-neutral, balancing increased taxation on carbon with rebates. However, it proved to be unpopular and contributed to the Liberal Party's defeat, earning the lowest vote share since Confederation.<ref>Template:Cite news</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>Template:Cite news</ref><ref>Findlay, Martha Hall. After the Green Shift Template:Webarchive. The Globe and Mail. 19 January 2009.</ref> The Conservative party won the election by promising to "develop and implement a North American-wide cap-and-trade system for greenhouse gases and air pollution, with implementation to occur between 2012 and 2015".<ref>Template:Cite news</ref>
In 2018, Canada enacted a revenue-neutral carbon levy starting in 2019,<ref>Greenhouse Gas Pollution Pricing Act Template:Webarchive, in force since 21 June 2018 (page visited on 26 October 2018).</ref><ref name="Nuccitelli">Template:Cite news</ref> fulfilling Prime Minister Justin Trudeau's campaign pledge.<ref name="Nuccitelli" /> The Greenhouse Gas Pollution Pricing Act applies only to provinces without provincial adequate carbon pricing.<ref name="Nuccitelli" /> As of September 2020, seven of thirteen Canadian provinces and territories use the federal carbon tax while three have developed their own carbon tax programs.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In December 2020, the federal government released an updated plan with a Template:CA$ per tonne per year increase in the carbon pricing, reaching Template:CA$ per tonne in 2025 and Template:CA$ per tonne in 2030.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Quebec became the first province to introduce a carbon tax.<ref name="Quebec to collect nation's 1st carbon tax">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name="Quebec government to implement carbon tax">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> The tax was to be imposed on energy producers starting 1 October 2007, with revenue collected used for energy-efficiency programs. The tax rate for gasoline is $CDN0.008 per liter, or about Template:CA$ per tonne of Template:Chem equivalent.<ref name="Where Carbon is Taxed">{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
The Liberal government claimed 80% of Canadians were receiving more money back via a carbon rebate but the tax was unpopular with many Canadians and became a political issue.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> In 2023, the Official Opposition refused to support a free trade bill between Canada and the Ukraine that added a new environmental chapter to "promote carbon pricing". Liberal Trade Minister Mary Ng stated, "We should applaud the Ukrainians for being able to negotiate an agreement and also fight climate change." Liberal House leader Karina Gould, argued the Tories were "abandoning Ukraine and not taking climate change seriously", and accused them of "American-style, right-wing politics". Pierre Poilievre, the leader of the Opposition, called the carbon tax stipulation "cruel" and stated, "It is disgusting, that Trudeau’s ideological obsession with taxing working-class people, seniors and suffering families has come ahead of what should have been a free trade agreement."<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
By the end of 2024, opinion polls showed the ruling Trudeau Liberals were 20 points behind the Conservative Party of Canada, which was using the slogan "Axe the Tax" in their platform.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Many Liberals, worried about projected losses in the 2025 federal election, pushed for Justin Trudeau to resign, which he eventually announced on January 6, 2025. The party former Governor of the Bank of Canada, Mark Carney, and within a few hours of being sworn in as Canada's 24th prime minister on March 14, 2025, Carney signed a declaration ending the consumer carbon tax and the rebate. Carney stated in his platform that "further measures to make up for the lost impact of the consumer carbon tax" would be implemented.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> Alberta Premier Danielle Smith warned of forthcoming increased industrial carbon taxes, which would be passed onto consumers without a rebate program in effect.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
United StatesEdit
A national carbon tax in the U.S. has been repeatedly proposed, but never enacted. For instance, on 23 July 2018, Representative Carlos Curbelo (R-FL) introduced H.R. 6463,<ref>H.R. 6463 https://www.congress.gov/bill/115th-congress/house-bill/6463 Template:Webarchive</ref> the "MARKET CHOICE Act", a proposal for a carbon tax in which revenue is used to bolster American infrastructure and environmental solutions.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> The bill was introduced in the House of Representatives, but did not become law.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
A number of organizations are currently advancing national carbon tax proposals. To address concerns from conservatives that a carbon tax would grow government and increase cost of living, recent proposals have centered around revenue-neutrality.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref name="auto" /> The Citizens' Climate Lobby (CCL), republicEn (formerly E&EI), the Climate Leadership Council (CLC), and Americans for Carbon Dividends (AFCD) support a revenue-neutral carbon tax with a border adjustment. The latter two organizations advocate for a specific framework called the Baker-Shultz Carbon Dividends Plan, which has gained national bipartisan traction since its announcement in 2017.<ref>Template:Citation</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> The central principle is a gradually rising carbon tax in which all revenues are rebated as equal dividends to the American people.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> This plan is co-authored by and named after Republican elder-statesmen James Baker and George Shultz.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref> It is also supported by companies including Microsoft, Pepsico, First Solar, American Wind Energy Association, Exxon Mobil, BP, and General Motors.<ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref><ref>{{#invoke:citation/CS1|citation |CitationClass=web }}</ref>
See alsoEdit
ReferencesEdit
Template:Climate change Template:Portal bar Template:Authority control